Page 1 of 29

283

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal – Vol.7, No.9

Publication Date: September 25, 2020

DOI:10.14738/assrj.79.8927.

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and

Exchange Rates Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria:

The Interest and Exchange Rates Channels

Elias A. Udeaja

Assistant Director, Research Department,

Central Bank of Nigeria

Nathan P. Audu

Country Economist, West African Monetary

Institute, Accra, Ghana.

Titus O. Obiezue

Assistant Manager, Research Department,

Central Bank of Nigeria

ABSTRACT

This paper examines the effectiveness ofthe interest and exchange rates

channels of monetary policy transmission mechanism. The paper

employed several statistical cum econometric methodology in a

baseline structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model to evaluate the

influence of policy shocks on selected endogenous variables; gross

domestic product (GDP), consumer price index (CPI), money supply

(MS), treasury bill rate (TBR) and nominal exchange rate (NER) for

Nigerian spanning 1981Q1 to 2020Q1. The contemporaneous

coefficients in the structural model reveals that key monetary

aggregates reacts positively to unexpected changes in the monetary

policy instruments. Furthermore, the variance decomposition results

indicate that shocks of the selected variables were found to be

important for interest rate growth in the short and longer horizons. The

exchange rate channel however appears to have a stronger impact on

prices. These results mean that depreciation of the nominal exchange

rate could be an external deflationary element, particularly for Nigeria.

Keywords: monetary policy, transmission, mechanism, structural shock.

INTRODUCTION

Monetary policy (MP) can be described as a central banks action aimed at influencing the

availability and cost of money and credit, as a means of achieving price stability and promoting

national economic goals. Specifically, MP is a mixture of actions considered to regulate the value,

supply and cost of credit in an economy in tandem with the anticipated level of economic activity.

Broadly, the objectives of monetary policy include; low interest rates, price stability, economic

growth, full employment, exchange rate stability, and balance of payments equilibrium.

Page 2 of 29

284

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

The monetary policy instruments currently in use in Nigeria include; the monetary policy rate

(MPR), open market operations (OMO), reserve requirements (cash and liquidity ratios), moral

suasion and exchange rate. The implementation of monetary policy revolves around the

manipulation of these instruments to influence the intermediate targets, such as, money supply,

interest rates, which would eventually impact on the real and external sectors of the economy. The

overall effect of these would result to changes in output growth, inflation rate and external reserve

position.

The linkages between monetary policy shocks and changes in output, employment and inflation are

known as the monetary policy transmission mechanism. This mechanism describes how changes in

monetary policy transmit through the financial system via interest rate, exchange rate and money

supply to the real economy. For example, in Nigeria changes in the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN)

monetary policy rate may impact on other short-term interest rates which in turn may affect lending

rates in the medium to long run and may ultimately affect domestic demand. Other channels may

include exchange rate and money/credit. Under the indirect approach, the link between monetary

policy and money stock, which determined by the money multiplier is emphasized under the

monetary targeting framework, which the bank adopted. Since the introduction of OMO as the main

instrument of monetary policy in 1993, the interest rate and to a large extent, the exchange rate

channels have been explicitly prominent in transmitting monetary policy impulses to the real

economy. However, the effectiveness or otherwise of these two channels have not been subjected

to empirical investigation.

The challenges that resulted from the global financial and economic crises had compelled monetary

authorities to adopt plethora of monetary policy measures. In Nigeria, such challenges include the

dwindling external reserves due to falling crude oil prices in the international market, low fiscal

buffers sustained pressure in the foreign exchange market due to low supply of foreign exchange,

and excess liquidity in the banking system. These developments have serious implications for both

internal and external balance and had attracted several monetary policy measures aimed at

restoring economic stability. Importantly, the falling crude oil price led to a drastic decline in

Nigeria’s foreign exchange earnings which resulted to a depreciation of the naira exchange rates at

both the interbank and BDC segments. Accordingly, the monetary policy posture of the Bank was

mottled to reflect the prevailing developments. The monetary policy rate (MPR) fluctuated between

11.0 and 13.0 per cent in 2015, and 11.0 to 14.0 per cent in 2016. The cash reserve ratio (CRR) was

increased to 22.5 per cent in 2016 from 20.0 per cent in 2015.

In addition, the symmetric interest rate corridor that was put at +/–200 basis points around the

MPR for standing facility window was altered to an asymmetric corridor of +200/–700 basis points

around MPR in 2015. This measure was aimed at discouraging dumping of funds at CBN and

promoting credit availability to the real sector. The asymmetric interest rate corridor was narrowed

to +200/-500 basis points in 2016. The open market operation (OMO) continued to be the primary

tool for liquidity management and was supplemented by reserve requirements, repurchase

transactions as we as interventions in the foreign exchange market.

Apart from few theoretical and empirical attempts on the monetary policy transmission in Nigeria

such as that of the CBN Research Department (2010), Chukwu (2013) and Hassan (2015), no study

had specifically examined the effectiveness of the interest and exchange rates channels of monetary

Page 3 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 285

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

policy shocks. Therefore, in order to achieve the primary objective of price stability by CBN, a better

understanding of the monetary transmission process is required to develop instruments that can

reinforce the efficacy of monetary policy transmission in Nigeria. A good knowledge of the dominant

channels of transmission would be critical to effective design and implementation of monetary

policy. This study intends to fill the existing gap in empirical literature on monetary policy

transmission in Nigeria through the channels of interest and exchange rates. Specifically, this study

will investigate empirically how monetary policy actions are transmitted to the real sector (output

and prices) of the economy through the interest and exchange rates channels and evaluate the

effectiveness, strengths, speed of monetary policy transmission through these channels. The

outcome would guide the Management of the Bank on policy choices for effective monetary policy

implementation.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows; following the introduction, Section 2 provides the

theoretical underpinnings and review of empirical literature on monetary policy transmission

mechanism. Section 3 discusses the recent monetary policy frameworks and initiatives of the Bank

and its effects on the real sector, Section 4 is on the methodology, estimation and analysis of results

and the last section focuses on the policy implications of the results, conclusion and policy

recommendation.

THE MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN NIGERIA

Theoretical literature

The transmission of monetary policy is the process through which monetary policy

pronouncements affect the real economy, especially the price level. It is usually long, variable with

uncertain time lags. The main transmission channels of monetary policy are discussed below:

Interest rate channel

According to the expectation hypothesis of the term structure, a rise in the short-term nominal

interest rate leads to an increase in the longer-term nominal interest rates. Since prices are assumed

to be sticky in the short-term, a reduction in the long-term real interest rate decreases the cost of

capital, and the money paid on interest bearing deposits such as treasury bills. As the cost of capital

falls firms increase their investment expenditure and households increase their consumption of

durable goods. These increase the aggregate demand, output and employment. In the traditional

Keynesian IS-LM model, the main channel of monetary policy transmission is the interest rate

channel. An expansionary monetary policy transmission is captured as follows:

M↑ → ir↓→ I↑→Y↑

where M stands for expansionary monetary policy, ir equals real interest rate, I connotes investment

spending and household spending on durable goods, and Y means output. This depicts that an

expansionary monetary policy would lead to a decline in real interest rates, which reduces the cost

of capital and increase investment and consumption spending, thereby increasing aggregate

demand and output.

The fact that real and not nominal interest rate impacts on spending shows that monetary policy

can stimulate the economy, even in a liquidity trap where nominal interest rates hit a floor of zero

as in the global financial crisis of 2008. When nominal interest rates is zero, an increase in money

Page 4 of 29

286

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

supply (M↑) would increase the expected price level (Pe↑), thus, the expected inflation (πe↑), thereby

reducing the real interest rate (ir, ↓) and stimulating spending through the interest rate channel

above: M↑ → Pe↑→ πe↑→ ir ↓→ I↑→Y↑. This shows that monetary policy will still be effective, when

nominal interest rates have been reduced to zero by the monetary authorities.

Exchange rate channel

Exchange rate channel encompasses interest rate effects for the reason that when domestic real

interest rates decreases, domestic deposits in local currency becomes unattractive, when compared

to deposits denominated in foreign currencies. This leads to a depreciation of the local currency

(E↓). The depreciation of the local currency, makes the domestic goods cheaper than foreign goods,

thereby leading to a rise in net exports (NX↑) and, thus, in aggregate output. The monetary

transmission mechanism through the exchange rate is captured as:

M↑ → ir ↓→ E↓→NX↑→Y↑

The effectiveness of the exchange rate channel is contingent on the reaction of the exchange rate to

monetary shocks, the exchange rate arrangement of the country and the degree of openness of the

economy. Nevertheless, the increasing interaction among economies and adoption of more flexible

exchange rates has attracted monetary authorities to understand the monetary policy transmission

mechanism through exchange rate effects on net exports.

Asset Price Channel

The asset price channel is divided into two channels: the equity price channel, and the housing and

land price channel.

The Equity Price Channel

The equity price channel is further divided into two: Tobin’s Q theory and wealth effect.

Tobin’s Q Theory

In Tobin’s Q theory, Q represent the ratio of market value of firms to the replacement cost of capital.

Therefore, if Q is high, the replacement cost of capital is low compared with the market price of

firms, as such new machinery and equipment capital would be cheaper, when compared to the

market value of business firms. Thus, investment spending will increase as the firm buys more lots

of new investment goods with only a small issue of equity. However, when Q is low, firms will not

procure new investment goods as the cost of capital is high compared with the market price of firms.

According to the monetarist school of thought, an expansionary monetary policy reduces interest

rates, making bonds less attractive relative to equities, thereby raising the price of equities. Higher

equity prices leads to increase in Q and thus higher investment spending. This is captured as follows:

M↑ → Pe↑→ Q↑→ I↑→Y↑

Wealth Effects

The wealth effect was promoted by Franco Modigliani. In his life-cycle model, consumption

spending was determined by the lifetime resources of the consumer which is consist with human

capital, financial wealth and real capital (Modigliani, 1971). According to Modigliani, stock is a major

Page 5 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 287

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

cause of financial wealth. As stock prices rise, the value of financial wealth rises so the consumers’

lifetime resources or wealth and total consumption.

M↑ → Pe↑→ Wealth↑→ Consumption↑→Y↑

The Housing and Land Price Channels

Likewise, housing and land prices are significant component of wealth and are very important

channels of monetary policy transmission. An increase in housing and land prices increase wealth

and consumption. As described in the wealth and Tobin’s Q channel, monetary expansion which

raises land and housing prices, raises the level of aggregate demand

Inflation expectation channel

The success of policies (monetary and fiscal) hinges on the expectations of economic agents.

According to Blinder (1998), a successful monetary policy emerges as a result of the effective

management of expectations not overnight interest rates. Milton Friedman’s theory of adaptive

expectations (inflation expectations are modeled based on simple extrapolation of past inflations)

was the first attempt at explaining expectations in monetary policy. The inflation expectations of

economic agents are transmitted to the economy as individuals bargain for higher wages and as

firms amend their prices. When the concern of monetary policy to decrease inflation drastically,

then, its efficiency is enhanced by its potential to influence inflation expectations. Consequently,

expectations about the future posture of monetary policy by economic agents feed back into the

present (Mordi, 2010).

Credit Channel (bank lending and balance sheet)

Monetary policy impacts on the real sector through its effect on the financial sector. Credit is an

important macroeconomic variable that enhances economic activity. Bank lending and balance

sheet channels arise as a result of asymmetric information problem in credit markets.

In the bank lending channel, expansionary monetary policies increase the quantity of bank loans

available by increasing the bank reserves and bank deposits. As bank loans increase, investment

spending will also rise. M↑ → Bank deposits↑→ Bank loans↑→ I↑→Y↑

As depicted above, unlike big firms that can directly access credit markets through bond and stock

markets without going through the banks, then the credit channel impacts more on smaller firms as

they are more dependent on bank loans. Bernanke & Blinder (1988) state that the lending channel

is effective when the following conditions are met:

1. Firms must not be perfectly indifferent between borrowing money from financial

institutions through borrowing money and loans from the general public by way of bonds. If

firms are unmoved between the two types of financing, then the reduction in supply of loans

would affect the firms.

2. The central bank should be able to influence the supply of loans through the use of monetary

instruments.

The balance-sheet channel operates through the net worth of business firms. Reduction in net worth

means that lenders have fewer indemnity for their loans, therefore, fatalities from adverse selection

are higher. A decline in net worth raises the adverse selection problem, thus, leading to a reduced

Page 6 of 29

288

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

lending to finance investment spending. Reduction in net worth of business firms also upsurges the

moral hazard problem as owners have reduced equity stake in their firms.

Monetary policy can affect the balance sheet of firms in various ways: Contractionary monetary

policy (CMP), that leads to a fall in equity prices (Pe) reduces the net worth of firms and leads to

lower investment spending (I) and aggregate demand (Y), because of the rise in adverse selection

and moral hazard problems (Taylor, 1995). This can be represented as follows:

M↓ → Pe ↓→ adverse selection↑ & moral hazard↑ →lending ↓→I↓→Y↓

Literature review

Monetary policy transmission channels provide central banks with precise valuation of the timing

and effect of their policies on the economy. A real-world grasp of how monetary policy actions are

transmitted to the real economy has been a major challenge to economists and policy makers. Some

early empirical research in this area were carried out by Bernanke & Blinder (1992), Sims (1992),

Taylor (1995), Grilli & Roubini (1995), Eichenbaum & Evans (1995), Mishkin (1996), Clarida &

Gertler (1997), and Christiano et al. (1998).

Kim & Roubini (2000) using estimated SVAR models proffered solutions to empirical anomalies (the

liquidity, price, exchange rate and forward discount bias puzzles) encountered by early research

that employed VAR in studying the effects of monetary policy in closed and open economies. The

monetary policy model developed by Kim & Roubini (2000) allow exchange rates to be

concomitantly affected by all the factors in the model, which transmits more to the floating exchange

rate regime of advanced economies. They find the effects of non-US G-7 monetary policy shocks on

exchange rates and macroeconomic variables to be consistent with the forecasts of a broad set of

theoretical models.

Using VAR and structural models, Angeloni et al. (2003) in their comprehensive study of how

monetary policy affects the euro area economy, find evidence of broad credit channels for many of

the Euro area countries. They find plausible euro-area wide monetary policy responses for prices

and output that are similar to those generally reported for the U.S. However, investment (relative

to consumption) seems to play a larger role in euro area monetary policy transmission than in the

U.S. Dungey and Pagan (2000) present an SVAR model of the Australian economy which models

macro-economic outcomes as transitory deviations from a deterministic trend.

In extension of their original work, Dungey and Pagan (2009) modified their original model by;

relating it to an emerging literature on DSGE modelling of small open economies and; allowing for

both transitory and permanent components in the series to show how this modification has an

impact upon the design of macroeconomic models. Nevertheless, they exclude bank credit variables

in their models. Using an SVAR approach also, Berkelmans (2005) examines the endogenous

relationship between credit and monetary policy of the Australian economy. They find that credit

shock results in higher inflation for about two years, but it is moderated as a result of monetary

policy’s response. Also, they suggest that a positive shock to policy interest rate lowers both

inflation and credit.

Page 7 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 289

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

Catao & Pagan (2010) find that changes in interest rate have a faster effect on output and prices in

Brazil and Chile relative to advanced economies, and exchange rate dynamics play an important role

in monetary transmission mechanisms in both countries. The active roles of interest and exchange

rates in monetary policy transmission are attributed to the floating exchange rates and significant

levels of capital account openness in both countries. However, the monetary transmission literature

on developing countries finds mixed evidence for the effectiveness of monetary policy. While

Disyatat & Vongsinsirikul (2003) and Ahmed & Islam (2006) find a weak bank lending channel for

Thailand and Bangladesh, respectively, Aleem (2010) finds that the banking sector plays a dominant

role in transmitting monetary policy to the real sector in India. Also, Afrin (2016) find that exchange

rate channel is less effective in the transmission process in Bangladesh, suggesting a high degree of

intervention in the foreign exchange market.

Given the floating nature of exchange rate regimes in the US and Australia, their SVAR structures

may not always be appropriate for developing countries like Nigeria, where exchange rates are

either following a managed float or pegged. This paper follows the block recursive approach of Afrin,

2016; considering that in Nigeria and Bangladesh, the exchange rate may synchronously impact on

other factors, such as real sector variables and monetary policy. The variables are not self-affected

contemporaneously. However, with monetary policy, a separate foreign exchange market can be

put in place for intervention to stabilize the exchange rates by the apex bank. In a developing

country like Nigeria, exchange rate cannot be allowed to be simultaneously affected by other

variables employed in the model. Also, for emerging small open economies, Nigeria and Bangladesh

have similar attributes. As such, the factors employed in our structural vector Autoregression

identification scheme are similar to that of Afrin (2016) for Bangladesh.

Also, the literature on exchange rate pass through (ERPT) approach employed the recursive

structural vector autoregression with Cholesky decomposition. Monacelli (2005), Smets and

Wouters (2002), Adolfson (2001) and Devereux (2001), in their separate study on a small open

economy with an optimal monetary policy opined that this may positively affected level of the

exchange rate pass through. The ordering of factors in the exchange rate pass through literature

were output gap, oil price, wholesale and consumer price inflation, exchange rate and import price

inflation. In their ordering, consumer price instead of the exchange rate was contemporaneously

affected by all foreign and domestic variables. This situation are commonly found in emerging and

developing countries as it reflects the nature of managed of exchange rate regimes they adopt.

McCarthy (2007) observed that exchange rate pass through have decreased considerably in the

economies of sub Saharan African countries since the mid-1990s. He also opined that there is a drop

of about 50 percent in exchange rate pass-through from the estimated coefficients. Razafimahefa

(2012) also finds that the pass-through is incomplete for SSA. For Nigeria, Adeyemi and Samuel

(2013) find a significantly huge exchange rate pass-through to inflation. They find that Nigeria’s

rising inflation was significantly attributed to exchange rate than actual money supply. Their study

employs a SVAR model for the Nigeria's economy which is in tandem with literature for a unified

SVAR identification akin to Bhattacharya et al. (2011) identification methodology for India

economy. Bhattacharya et al. (2011) assume that the exchange rate of a small economy is not

allowed to move contemporaneously with other macro variables; rather, price is affected by

exchange rate and other variables as in highly intervened foreign exchange markets.

Page 8 of 29

290

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

The main objective of monetary policy in Nigeria is the conservation of domestic exchange rate and

price stability for the promotion of sustainable economic growth and external sector viability. This

goal has however, been undermined by persistent liquidity overhang, fiscal dominance, oligopolistic

banking system, and dualistic financial markets (Nnanna, 2001). Ndekwu (2013) employed an OLS

and a dynamic logarithmic form VAR to study monetary policy transmission mechanism to the real

sector of the Nigerian economy from 1981 to 2008, find that the credit channel is the corner stone

of monetary policy transmission to the real sector economy, while exchange and interest rates

channels had a feeble impact on the real sector economy. However, Abdullahi (2014) in assessing

the effectiveness of monetary policy transmission mechanisms in Nigeria from 1980 to 2010 find

that credit channel is inefficient and exchange rate channel is weak, while interest rate channel was

found to be the greatest determinant channel for monetary policy transmission in Nigeria.

Obafemi and Ifere (2015) using quarterly data from 1970:1 – 2013:4, employed FAVAR model with

53 variables to evaluate the channel of transmission of monetary shocks in Nigeria, they found that

credit and interest rates channels were the most important channels for transmission of monetary

shocks, then the money and exchange rate channels. In addition, stock channel was insignificant in

explaining transmission shock process in Nigeria. Uma et al. (2014) also show that exchange rate,

credit and interest rate channels were amongst the channels of monetary policy transmission to the

Nigerian economy.

To crown it all, the review of extant literature on Nigeria shows gaps that the interest and exchange

rates channel of monetary transmission policy has not been explored thoroughly. Thus, the whole

monetary policy transmission mechanism in remains Nigeria unclear and deserves more empirical

studies.

STYLIZED FACT OF NIGERIA’S EXCHANGE RATE AND MACROECONOMIC FUNDAMENTALS

Trend analysis of naira–US dollar exchange rate

The trend analysis of quarterly Nigeria’s naira–US dollar exchange rate for the period 1985Q1 –

2017Q1 is presented in Figure 1. The naira–US dollar exchange rate hovered around N0.89 and

N9.87 to a US dollar during the period 1985Q1 – 1992Q2, before it depreciated sharply to

N29.61/US$1 in 1994Q4. This led to the liberalization of the foreign exchange market in Nigeria,

Following the liberalization of the exchange policy in 1995, the naira–US dollar exchange rate

further appreciated to N80.74/US$1 in 1995Q2 from N29.61/US$1 in 1994Q4. It however remained

relatively stable around N80.74/US$1 – N87.58/US$1 till 1999Q4.

From 2000Q1, it depreciated steadily to N135.19/US$1 in 2004Q2 before appreciating to

N117.67/US$1 in 2008Q3. Since then, the naira–US dollar exchange rate has maintained a sharp

depreciation, though it steadied and averaged N306.20/US$1 between 2016Q3 and 2019Q4, before

depreciating further to N361.20/US$1 in 2020Q1, occasioned by the devaluation of the naira to curb

speculative attacks and the depleting reserves as a result of the plunge in oil price in the

international market as well as the harmonization of the country’s various exchange rates.

Page 12 of 29

294

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

Hamilton (1994), opined that in order to recuperate the mechanical parameters from the abridged

form model, the order condition must be fulfilled. This implies that the total number of factors in

the covariance matrix must be the same. The variance covariance matrix of the abridged form is

shown in equation (3).

? = 6(;$;7) @A ? = (!"

=>)? (!"

=>)7

C B$

(3)

C

For identification to be achieved, it is expected that the factors in ( and !" are convalesced from

the abridged form. In equation (3) E encloses F(F + 1)/2 factors, and has F(F + 1) free variables

in equation (3), we then imposed 2FH − F − F(F + 1)/2 constraints on ( and !". The imposition

of F(F − 1) constraint is meant to constrain ( to be transverse, there by attaining an identification

of at least F(F − 1)/2 constraints are enforced on !". When modeling the Cholesky decomposition

in the VAR, !" is measured as a deltoid. Nevertheless, a structural VAR !" can take any form until

it has sufficient constraint.

The Structural Vector Autoregression Estimates (SVAR) Model for Nigeria

We adopted the augmented Kim and Roubini’s (2000), non-recursive SVAR methodology to

investigate the effectiveness of monetary transmission mechanisms in Nigeria. The shocks in a

mechanical SVAR can be identified by imposing some constraints in the baseline SVAR. A typical

SVAR for the Nigeria economy contains seven equations and factors as shown by the Xt vector in

equation (4):

&$ = (JKL$ , NLO$ , PQRL$ , JLS$ , NT$ , UVO$, P6O$, ) (4)

From equation (4), COPt represent the world crude oil price in terms of the US dollar, MPRt refers to

the Central Bank of Nigeria monetary policy rate, NGDPt is the nominal gross domestic production, CPIt

means the consumer price index, MSt connotes the monetary aggregate, TBRt represent the monetary

policy instrument (as three-month TBRs), and NERt means the nominal exchange rate.

From equation (4), the first identification arrangement is the standard approach which imposes a

recursive structure of the VAR that shows the connection in the abridged-form inaccuracies (errors)

and the structural disturbance is presented in equation (5).

(5)

Unlike the recursive identification, in identifying the structural VAR, the authors employed Amisano

and Gianini (1997) strategy. In Amisano, et al framework, sufficient constraints are imposed on

21

31 32

41 42 43

51 52 53 54

61 62 63 64 65

71 72 73 74 75 76

1 0 0 0 0 00

1 0 0 0 00

1 0 0 00

1 0 00

1 00

1 0

1

COP COP

t t

MPR MPR

t t

NGDP NGDP

t t

CPI CP

t t

MS

t

TBR

t

NER

t

u

u

u

e b e b b e

bbb e

e bbbb

e bbbbb

e bbbbbb

é ù é ù ê ú ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú = ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú ë û ë û

I

MS

t

TBR

t

NER

t

u

u

u

u

é ù

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú ë û

Page 13 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 295

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

matrix !" and (. The system can be said to be justly identified, if requires 4(34 − 1) / 2 or

24H– 4(4 + 1) / 2 or 176 = 2(11H) − 11(11 + 1) / 2 constraints on !" and (. We are required

to impose 70 constraints on ( which is presumed the diagonal matrix in our model), also, additional

21 constraints must be placed on !" before the system can be justly identified.

The constraints imposed on the non-recursive simultaneous associations amongst the factors are

presented in equation (6). The left-hand side of equation is the baseline SVAR while the constants

[\] show that factor j instantaneously affects parameter i. Equation (5) shows the justly identified

system !";$ = (3$ .

(6)

The crude oil price represents external shocks. The domestic factor shocks do not have any

consequence on the exogenous variable simultaneously. Yet, the monetary policy rate reacts

positively and instantaneously to the movement in crude oil price. This is because the Nigerian

Central Bank tightens monetary policy whenever it encounter crude oil price shock. The exchange

and interest rates as well as the aggregate money are expected to affect the level of economic activity

(output) with a one period lag. The price level responds instantaneously to the GDP and nominal

exchange rate.

We included exchange rate in our model because it is lead indicator for price stability adjustment

in Nigeria. Furthermore, as crude oil price is determined by the government below the international

level, the domestic price is not supposed to react at the same time to the oil price. As Nigeria is the

seventh largest exporter of the crude oil, dollars play a crucial role in the economy of the country. It

is expected that GDP positively responds to crude oil price. Money demand is expected to respond

simultaneously to the interest rate (TBR), the price level (CPI), and GDP. The next factor is broad

money supply (MS). The monetary authority which sets the interest rate after considering the

current values of the crude oil price, money, exchange rate, and more significantly the country’s

anchor interest rate and the lagged values of all parameters in Xt.

The inclusion of exchange rate variable in the model, is meant to capture the pass through effect.

The reason for the addition of exchange rate and money the interest rate function simultaneously

is that the data on these variables are available instantaneously. However, for the monetary

authority, the data of important variables such as output and the price level are not available at

once, so these factors were not built-in in the monetary authority reaction function. The interest

rate is expected to responds positively to nominal exchange rate and money supply. In conclusion,

21

31

43 47

53 54 56

61 62 65 67

71 72 73 74 75 76

1000000

100000

010000

00 100

00 1 0

00 1

1

COP COP

t t

MPR MPR

t t

NGDP NGDP

t t

CPI CPI

t t

MS MS

t t

TBR T

t t

NER

t

u

u

u

u

u

u

u

e b e b e

b b e

bb b e

bb b b

bbbbbb

é ùé ù ê úê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú = ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú ë û ë û

BR

NER

t

e

e

é ù

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú

ê ú ë û

Page 21 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 303

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

Figure 8: Responses to a positive monetary policy rate

The peak impact occurs by 1.0%, this was found after 10 quarters of the shock and the response are

both long-lasting and statistically significant. The response on the price level is small, though

statistically significant. Prices do not begin to decline until about two quarters and rise, before

falling in a hump-shaped. The peak impact was reached after 3 quarters. In literature, the initial

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to COP

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to MPR

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to NGDP

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to CPI

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to MS

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to TBR

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of MPR to LNER

Page 22 of 29

304

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

positive response of prices to a tightening monetary policy shock is referred to as the “price puzzle”.

Moreover, monetary aggregate falls after the shock and bottoms out just after one quarter, in

addition to NER’s rising and peaking after five quarter and falls immediately.

Figure 3 shows the impulse response functions for all variables are affected by oil price shocks.

Following negative oil price shock, output in Nigeria declined, the impact of oil price shock on output

occurs one quarter after the shock. Also, COP has negative effects on MPR. Furthermore, price level

is affected simultaneously by oil price shock, price decreases slowly one quarter after oil price

shock. Oil price innovation also has negative response to TBR. Impulse response shows TBR falls

due to oil price shock. Moreover, an oil price shock has both negative effects on monetary aggregate

and positive effects on NER. However, MS falls and NER rises one quarter after the sock.

Figure 4 depicts the impulse response functions for all variables are affected by MPR shock. As

predicted, MPR has a positive influence on TBR of Nigeria as this country is pegged to USD.

Furthermore, MPR shock has negative effects on output. Twenty two basis points of MPR shock

increases GDP of 0.02% at 10 quarters after the shocks. Meanwhile, MPR innovation has a negative

effect on MS and CPI, and a positive effect on NER.

Table 6 reveals each variable’s variance decompositions at forecasted horizons of two through 10

quarters. Variance decompositions display percentage shares of variable movement encountering

different shocks. Columns of variance decomposition show percentage changes of each variable that

faced with shock and now the percentage change is adding up to 100%.

Table 6: Variance Decomposition: Interest and Exchange rate Channel

Variance

Decomposition Period COP MPR NGDP CPI MS TBR NER

NGDP

2 2.22 0.02 22.28 61.68 7.50 1.42 4.89

4 2.07 0.01 23.71 59.91 8.49 1.73 4.08

8 1.84 0.01 26.59 56.19 9.79 2.10 3.48

10 1.82 0.01 28.50 53.75 10.35 2.31 3.24

CPI

2 0.67 0.00 43.12 54.50 1.50 0.07 0.13

4 0.58 0.00 46.02 51.57 1.70 0.05 0.08

8 0.45 0.00 49.94 47.70 1.62 0.11 0.18

10 0.36 0.00 54.60 43.08 1.37 0.17 0.42

MS

2 0.21 0.01 37.05 61.14 0.00 0.51 1.07

4 0.15 0.01 38.37 60.00 0.00 0.45 1.03

8 0.15 0.00 38.90 59.61 0.01 0.40 0.93

10 0.19 0.00 37.98 60.64 0.05 0.35 0.79

TBR

2 0.05 0.05 44.75 29.18 0.21 0.49 25.27

4 0.05 0.05 48.79 30.18 0.20 0.47 20.25

8 0.10 0.06 46.80 31.78 1.94 0.57 18.75

10 0.39 0.04 42.41 40.88 2.62 0.54 13.12

NER

2 0.61 0.00 44.73 52.90 0.14 1.31 0.32

4 0.50 0.00 47.55 50.23 0.12 1.23 0.38

8 0.45 0.00 50.65 47.14 0.11 1.13 0.51

10 0.45 0.00 53.43 44.31 0.11 1.03 0.67

Note: Factorization – Structural, Source: Author's Compilation using Eviews

Page 24 of 29

306

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

Figure 9: Responses to a positive interest rate

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of NGDP to TBR

-4

-2

0

2

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of CPI to TBR

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LMS to TBR

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of TBR to TBR

-10

-5

0

5

10

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of NER to TBR

Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Page 27 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 309

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

Figure12: Responses to a positive monetary policy rate on Nigeria

CONCLUSIONS

The role of the interest rate and exchange rate channel in Nigeria was assessed in this paper. The

authors adopted an open-economy methodology to estimate SVAR model with contemporaneous

restrictions to analyze the effects of each channel. Comparison of recursive VAR results and non- recursive SVAR results indicates that better forecasting and estimation is obtained when SVAR

method is applied. Contemporaneous coefficient of monetary policy reaction reveals that Nigeria's

monetary agency raises the interest rate when encountering the unexpected increases in MS,

although Nigeria exchange rate is pegged to US dollar, monetary aggregate decreases with an

unexpected increase in interest rates.

The analysis of the results shows that shocks to interest rate effect output, and also has a major

impact on prices over the sample period. These findings are generally consistent with findings in

other countries, using the similar methodology. However, significant fluctuations in movements of

economic activity relating to systematic reaction to monetary aggregate and foreign stocks such as

the crude oil price. The authors find that a depreciation shock in the nominal exchange rate leads to

a rise or an increase in the price level, although the impact of an interest rate shock on prices is not

strong in Nigeria.

However, as in many developing countries like Nigeria the exchange rate channel appears to have a

stronger impact on prices. These results mean that depreciation of the NER could be an external

deflationary element, particularly for Nigeria. Allowing more flexibility in the exchange rate can

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to LCOP

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to MPR

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to LNGDP

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to LCPI

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to LMS

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to TBR

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of LNER to LNER

Page 28 of 29

310

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol.7, Issue 9, September-2020

strengthen the exchange rate channel for Nigeria that pegging the naira - US dollar, can open more

doors for autonomy for the Central Bank of Nigeria.

References

Abdullahi, B. M. (2014). Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism and the Nigerian Economy. Being a Master of

Science dissertation presented to the Department of Banking and Finance, Faculty of Business Administration,

University of Nigeria, Nsukka

Adeyemi, O. A. and E. Samuel, (2013). Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Consumer Prices in Nigeria. European Scientific

Journal, 9(25). 110-123

Adolfson, M. (2001). Monetary Policy with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through. Sveriges Riks Bank Working

Paper Series, No. 127.

Afrin, S. (2016). Monetary policy transmission in Bangladesh: Exploring the lending channel. Journal of Asian

Economics 49. 45-67

Ahmed, S. and E. Islam, (2006). Interest Rate Responsiveness of Investment Spending in Bangladesh: A VAR Approach.

Policy Analysis Unit, Research Department, Bangladesh Bank Working Paper Series: WP 0608

Aleem, A. (2010).Transmission mechanism of monetary policy in India. Journal of Asian Economics, 21(2). 186-197

Angeloni, I. and M. Ehrmann, (2003). Monetary policy transmission in the euro area: Any changes after EMU.

European Central Bank Working Paper Series, 240

Amisano, G., and C. Giannini, (1997). Topics in structural VAR econometrics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

Berkelmans L. (2005). Credit and Monetary Policy: An Australian SVAR. Economic Research Department Reserve Bank

of Australia, Research Discussion Paper 2005-06

Bernanke, B. S. and A. S. Blinder, (1988). Credit, Money and Aggregate Demand. American Economic Review, 78(2).

435-439

Bernanke, B. S. and A. S. Blinder, (1992). The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of Monetary Transmission.

American Economic Review 82(4). 901–921.

Blinder, A. S. (1998). Central Banking in Theory and Practice. London, England: The MIT Press Cambridge,

Catão, L. and A. Pagan, (2010). The Credit Channel and Monetary Transmission in Brazil and Chile: A Structural VAR

Approach. Working Papers Central Bank of Chile 579,

Central Bank of Nigeria (2010). Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism. In Nigeria, Research Department.

Cheung, Y. W., and K. S. Lai, (1993). Long-run purchasing power parity during the recent float. Journal of International

Economics, 34, 181-192.

Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. & Evans, C. L. (1998). Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What

End? NBER Working Papers 6400, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

Clarida, R. and M. Gertler (1997). How the Bundesbank Conducts Monetary Policy in, NBER Chapters, National Bureau

of Economic Research, Inc

Chukwu A. C. (2013). Measuring the effects of monetary policy innovations in Nigeria: A structural vector

autoregressive (SVAR) approach. African Journal of Accounting, Economics, Finance and Banking Research, 5(5). 18-

40.

Devereux, M, (2001). Monetary Policy, Exchange Rate Flexibility and Exchange Rate Pass Through. In Revisiting the

Case for Flexible Exchange Rates. Bank of Canada.

Disyatat, P. and P. Vongsinsirikul (2003). Monetary Policy and the Transmission Mechanism in Thailand. Journal of

Asian Economics, 14 (4). 34-49

Dungey, M. and A. Pagan, (2009). Extending a SVAR Model of the Australian Economy. Economic Record, 85 (268).1-

20

Page 29 of 29

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.79.8927 311

Udeaja, E. A., Audu, N. P., & Obiezue, T. O. (2020). The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy Shocks in Nigeria: The Interest and Exchange Rates

Channels. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 7(9) 283-311.

Dungey, M. and A.R. Pagan (2000). A Structural VAR Model of the Australian Economy. Economic Record, 76. 321-342.

Eichenbaum, M. and L. Evans, (1995), Some Empirical Evidence on the Effects of Shocks to Monetary Policy on

Exchange Rates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(4). 975-1009

Gottschalk, J., and F. Höppner, (2001). Measuring the effects of monetary policy in Europe: The role of systematic

policy. Kiel Working Paper.

Grilli, V. and N.Roubini, (1995). Liquidity and exchange rates: Puzzling evidence from the G-7 countries. Mimeo, Yale

University.

Hall, S. G. (1989). Maximum likelihood estimation of cointegration vectors: An example of the Johansen procedure.

Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 51, 213-218.

Hamilton, J. D. (1994). Time series analysis. Princeton. NJ: Princeton University Press.

Hassan A. (2015). Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in Nigeria: evidence from VAR Approach. Eastern

Mediterranean University, Gazimagusa, North Cyprus, August.

Ibrahim, M. H. (2006). Integration or segmentation of the Malaysian equity market: An analysis of pre- and post- capital controls. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 11(4), 424-443.

Johansen, S. (1992). Testing weak exogeneity and the order of cointegration in UK money demand data. Journal of

Policy Modeling, 14(3). 313-334.

Kim, S., and N. Roubini, (2000). Exchange rate anomalies in the industrial countries: A solution with a structural VAR

approach. Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 561-586.

McCarthy, J. (2007). Pass-through of Exchange Rates and Import Prices to Domestic Inflation in Some Industrialized

Economies. Eastern Economic Journal, 33(4). 511-537.

Mishkin, F. S. (1996). Symposium on the Transmission Mechanism. National Bureau of Economic Research Working

Paper No. 5464

Modigliani, F. (1970). The life-cycle hypothesis and intercountry differences in the saving ratio. In W. A. Eltis, M. FG.

Scott, and J. N. Wolfe, eds., Induction, growth, and trade: essays in honour of Sir Roy Harrod, Oxford. Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary Policy in a Low Pass-Through Environment. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking.

37(6).1047-1066

Ndekwu, E. C. (2013). An analysis of the monetary policy transmission mechanism and the real economy in Nigeria.

Central Bank of Nigeria Occasional Papers No. 43.

Nnanna, O. J. (2001). Monetary policy framework in Africa: The Nigerian experience. Discussion paper, South African

Reserve Bank Conference.

Obafemi, N. F. and E. O. Ifere, (2015). Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Nigeria: A Comparative Analysis.

Research in World Economy, 6(4). 93-103

Razafimahefa I. F. (2012). Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Sub-Saharan African Economies and its Determinants. IMF

Working Paper WP/12/141

Sims, C. A. (1992). Interpreting the Macroeconomic Time Series Facts: The Effects of Monetary Policy, Cowles

Foundation Discussion Papers 1011, Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University

Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2002). Openness, Imperfect Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Monetary Policy. European

Central Bank Working Paper No. 128.

Taylor, J. B. (1995). The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Empirical Framework. Journal of Economic

Perspective, 9(4). 11-26

Uma, K. E., B. M. Ogbonna and P. Obidike, (2014). Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism In Nigeria: An Overview.

Proceedings of International Academic Conferences at, International Institute of Social and Economic Sciences.