Page 1 of 7

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal – Vol. 8, No. 7

Publication Date: July 25, 2021

DOI:10.14738/assrj.87.10475. Johnson, C. (2021). Understanding Inflation Policy, 2021. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 8(7). 1-7.

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Understanding Inflation Policy, 2021

Clark Johnson1

I will not predict an inflation level, nor will I anticipate inflation’s impact on the stock market

over the next 12 months. Instead, here are some conceptual matters to help understand what

might unfold.

MONETARY TARGETS

Just as after the financial crisis and Great Recession of 2007-2009, many commentators, and

some professional economists, now predict a damaging level of inflation to result from Central

Bank policy, combined with deficit spending, in the wake of the 2020-2021 pandemic. While

critics in the earlier case cited sharp increases in the monetary base (currency and bank

reserves), current monetarists, including Steve Hanke and Tim Congdon, cite increases in much

broader money supply indicators (eg, M4 – which includes most short-term, liquid assets). M4

is indeed up sharply over the last several months, so perhaps critics will be proven correct this

time; but that will depend upon events that have not yet arrived and decisions that have not yet

been made.

Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell and Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen have commented

publicly that they believe current inflationary pressures are manageable, and may even aid in

recovery from the slowdown. Paul Krugman has argued (NYT, May 6 and May 13, 2021) that

recent price jumps can be attributed to pandemic-linked supply bottlenecks and other

temporary factors. And Bloomberg reported on May 21, 2021:

For a sign that accelerating inflation may be fleeting, look to the housing industry,

Conor Sen writes for Bloomberg Opinion. Rising prices are starting to cool

demand, anecdotal evidence suggests builders are starting to take a pause, and

lumber prices have responded. A start-and-stop growth environment is unlikely to

sustain a higher level of inflation.

In the 1920s, John Maynard Keynes argued that inflation was a monetary phenomenon. While

Keynes wrote different things at different times, many Keynesian economists focused on

interest rate management as the essential policy tool for managing inflation and growth. The

“Taylor rule”, proposed in 1992, has also deployed interest rate management to stabilize price

and growth performance. Highlighting a different policy lever, Milton Friedman argued in the

1950s and 1960s that changes in money supply would lead “with long and variable lags” to

changes in price levels. By the 1980s and 1990s, however, many or most international

monetary authorities were targeting inflation levels directly rather than locking into interest

rates or tracking money supply indicators. Late in his life, Friedman adapted his view to agree

1 Clark Johnson is Economics Advisor for Trade Engine LLC. This paper reflects his views alone.

Page 2 of 7

2

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol. 8, Issue 7, July-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

that central banks could target inflation directly rather than seek to stabilize an intermediate

variable. 2

Consider a bit of algebra. Imagine that we must solve for several economic variables using

simultaneous equations – so that a change in one variable affects all of the others. Now choose

the variables: one or more interest rates, one or more money supply indicators, a variable for

the velocity of money (an indicator of perceived uncertainty and demand for liquidity); also,

one or more inflation indicators, a rate of real GDP growth (RGDP), a rate of nominal GDP

growth (NGDP), an exchange rate indicator. We can add more variables if we want to test for

other relationships: eg, the fiscal deficit or the current account balance. The first group is for

intermediate variables – interest rates, money supply, velocity. The second group are end- variables – the rate of inflation, the rate of economic growth, exchange rates. Policy-makers

must answer for performance in reaching end-variables; intermediate variable targets are

subordinate.

It has long been clear that central banks could target an outside standard as an end-variable,

hence that a currency’s value could be fixed to another currency or to a gold or silver price –

whereby we get a sterling standard, a gold standard, etc. What we have learned in recent

decades is that monetary policy can also target an inflation indicator; and we can ask, still more

recently, if we can target an inflation indicator, why not a growth indicator? Or a hybrid of the

two?

What took so long? Some targets are not useable; solving equations for some variables may

bring damaging volatility to the behavior of others. Eg, an aggressive target of 3 or 4 percent

annual growth in RGDP in the US or UK might be reachable only by accepting a growing rate of

price increases. An inflation target, or an NGDP target might lead to exchange rate instability

that some would deem excessive. (For example, NGDP growth in the US was anemic during the

first half of 2008, which suggests that monetary policy was restrictive; but the dollar fell to an

all-time low against the euro in July 2008, evidence, by that measure, that US money may have

been too easy.3) But an NGDP growth target has the advantage of facilitating more inflation

when the economy is weak, and encourages a tighter policy when the economy is growing more

rapidly. An NGDP target can help a monetary authority to achieve the old central bank objective

of “leaning against the wind.”4

In August 2020, the Federal Reserve announced that it would revise its “fixed” inflation target

(set for at least the last decade at 2 percent annually, a target usually undershot in practice,) to

an “average” inflation target (AIT), still set at 2 percent annually. In some recent months – using

the Fed’s preferred core inflation indicator -- US price inflation has exceeded the 2 percent rate,

2 Lars E. O. Swenson (2008), “What Have Economists Learned About Monetary Policy in the Last 50 years?” p. 3.

https://larseosvensson.se/files/papers/Buba%20709.pdf . Friedman died in 2006.

3 The 2008 policy question deserves another paper. It is discussed, not quite adequately, in Clark Johnson, “Reasserting

Monetary Policy: Sumner’s Nominal GDP Targeting and Beyond”, Applied Economics and Finance, Mar 2017.

http://redfame.com/journal/index.php/aef/issue/view/91

4 Inter alia, see George Selgin, Less Than Zero: the Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy (Cato, 2018);

and Scott Sumner, “The Case for Nominal GDP Targeting” (Mercatus, October 2012)

https://www.mercatus.org/publications/monetary-policy/case-nominal-gdp-targeting

Page 3 of 7

3

Johnson, C. (2021). Understanding Inflation Policy, 2021. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 8(7). 1-7.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.87.10475

and perhaps the 3 percent rate. The Economist (April 17, 2021) challenged Fed officials on the

implementation of AIT:

A new monetary-policy framework it adopted in August dictates that it should push

inflation temporarily higher than its target after recessions, to make up lost ground.

The problem is that nobody knows by how much or for how long it wants inflation

to overshoot after the pandemic. With the risks of an inflationary episode greater

than they have been in years, the ambiguity is an unfortunate additional source of

uncertainty.https://www.economist.com/leaders/2021/04/17/the-fed-should- explain-how-it-will-respond-to-rising-inflation?itm_source=parsely-api

The Fed resists announcing that nominal GDP is an important policy target – perhaps because

it was not so many years ago that it formally announced an inflation objective, and it hopes not

to appear inconstant? In any event, announcing an NGDP target would in fact overcome the

ambiguity implicit in an AIT. As the real growth component of NGDP grew, the Fed would be

committed to reducing the inflation component. Quite plausibly, the Fed is now working with

an unannounced NGDP target.

Surely relevant in estimating near-term inflation prospects is that we consider another end- variable: the dollar exchange rate. The dollar has been nearly flat from 1.21 to the euro on

December 31, 2020 to the identical rate on June 12, 2021. Over the same period, the dollar fell

by just over 3 percent against sterling, while rising by 6 percent against the Japanese yen; these

are almost routine fluctuations. There is no data from FX markets to suggest that unusual US

inflation (or deflation) is imminent. This evidence is quite different from that for volatility

during the Great Recession: a 20-odd percent drop in the dollar-euro value from late 2007 into

July 2008, followed by a dollar recovery of the same proportion from that date into November

2008.

For the moment, the Federal Reserve appears to retain control.

CAPITAL FLOWS AND FISCAL DEFICITS

In an important new book, Trade Wars are Class Wars5, authors Matthew Klein and Michael

Pettis argue that current account surplus countries, led by China and Germany, under-consume

relatively to national income because of the way income is distributed domestically. This

argument is a reversal of the conventional view that the US over-consumes and under-saves.

But Klein-Pettis are on solid ground inasmuch as trade deficits -- including for the US over

several decades -- and surpluses are “nearly always” induced by financial transfers. 6 The

authors bring together consideration of growth and inflation on one side with discussion of

damage from income inequality (“class wars”) on the other. Their study deserves a longer

review than it will get here, but I offer a conclusion and an inference.

5 Matthew C. Klein and Michael Pettis, Trade Wars are Class Wars: How Rising Inequality Distorts the Global

Economy and Threatens World Peace (Yale, 2020). 6 Robert Mundell, “Trade Balance Patterns as Global General Equilibrium: The Seventeenth Approach to the Balance of

Payments,” in Mario Baldassarri, Luigi Paganetto, Edmund S. Phelps, International Economic Interdependence,

Patterns of Trade Balance and Economic Policy Coordination (St. Martins, 1992); p. 49.

Page 4 of 7

4

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol. 8, Issue 7, July-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

When China or Germany (or Japan, the Netherlands, or any country seeking to add to its

national reserves7) consume less than they produce, large amounts of savings look abroad for

placement and safe harbor, just as large amounts of surplus product look for markets. As the

US dollar is the de facto world currency, the equivalent of hundreds of billions of dollars of

foreign savings seek refuge every year in US dollar instruments – preferably treasury or

government agency issues. The inflow of finance to the US (and, to a lesser extent, to Britain,

France, Canada and Australia) makes it inevitable that these countries will consume more than

they produce, hence that they will run current account deficits. Problematic consequences for

deficit countries have included 1) a flood of manufacturing imports8; 2) skewing of income

toward financial sectors that manage the capital transfers; and 3) lots of capital sloshing around

that will increase debt-to-income ratios in deficit countries, and be drawn into speculative

vehicles, eg subprime mortgages in the US prior to 2008.

To “fix” this global imbalance would require pressure on China, Germany and others to

redistribute more income down to households. For China, Klein and Pettis suggest increased

dividends from state-owned enterprises to be paid to employees, a wealth fund, recognition of

property rights, an income tax for higher-earners, lower consumption taxes, and an end to the

hukou system (which restricts movement and re-location.) For Germany, they recommend

higher inheritance taxes, lower taxes on most labor, and regulatory integration with the

European Union – including with what have been deficit countries within the bloc. For both, the

authors recommend fiscal deficits that should be used to direct savings to domestic purposes.

(The authors propose an international conference, call it Bretton Woods II, to accomplish this.)

If we do not see the kind of reform that would fix systemic imbalances, the US might soon look

for ways to discourage or block massive capital inflows. Current trade imbalances result from

these capital movements – not the other way around -- so any effort to address the problem

through the usual “trade” negotiations will fail.

Absent such reform, the US could explicitly provide more of the debt instruments that are in

such international demand (including for the purpose of augmenting national reserves across

much of the developing world); that is, the US might run larger budget deficits. Very low, even

sub-zero interest rates on US and several European treasury securities suggest that supply of

such securities does not meet global demand. Klein-Pettis note that there is now no shortage

of funds for corporate or other private sector outlays, and indeed that corporations, net, are

spending less than they generate in cash flow, and are often using excess cash to repurchase

7 Also: during 1999-2013, the world’s currency reserves grew from $1.9T to 11.6 T, the bulk of it held in dollars; to

grow reserves at such a rate required constraint on domestic expenditure in much of the world. Stastica. “Development

of Global Currency Reserves from 1995 to 2019.” https://www.statista.com/statistics/247281/development-of-foreign- exchange-reserves-worldwide/ 8 Take a stylized example. Imagine a world with two countries, US and CH, each with 100 units of production (50 each

of goods and services) and 100 units of consumption. Now imagine that CH doubles production to 200, but its

domestic consumption stays at 100 units. CH then exports 100 units of capital to US – which absorbs the capital and

increases its consumption to 200. It is easier for CH to export goods than to exports services, so most of the increased

capital in the US will go to consuming imported goods. The US as a whole is better off; it consumes more goods, and,

because it is richer than previously, also demands more services. Consequently, a portion of the 50 units of production

capacity in the US that previously went to producing goods will shift to providing services. Some US workers who

previously produced goods will have lost their jobs. The magnitude and composition of these shifts will vary from one

situation to the next. Also see, eg, Ronald McKinnon (2013), “The US Savings Deficiency, Current Account Deficits,

and Deindustrialization: Implications for China”; in Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 35, Issue 3.

Page 5 of 7

5

Johnson, C. (2021). Understanding Inflation Policy, 2021. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 8(7). 1-7.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.87.10475

stock. They cite evidence that US private equity firms are unable to deploy trillions of dollars.9

Hence, they argue, this is not the time to funnel massive international savings into private sector

projects in deficit countries. It would be more stabilizing, and better for longer term growth, if

the US were to run larger fiscal deficits and hence use proceeds – as suggested above for China

and Germany -- to upgrade infrastructure and to counter growing income inequality.

Whether or not anyone in the Biden Administration is using such an argument to justify

growing fiscal deficits, this is the direction US fiscal policy is moving. Some will imagine massive

fiscal deficits as a harbinger of inflation to come. Indeed, the longer-term impact of growing

deficits is problematic; one hopes that action will be taken as indicated to moderate capital

flows, and hence to reduce demand for US government securities. But in the short- and medium- term, there will be little pressure to monetize US government debt because so many foreign

central banks, national wealth funds and individuals want to hold it.

A premise in Klein-Pettis is that systemic aggregate demand is stagnant because international

manufacturing capacity is abundant and income distribution tilts away from consumption.

Skepticism is in order: the authors often under-state the importance of monetary factors.

Indeed, they see both the US depression after 1929 and the Japanese slowdown in the 1990s as

driven at least in part by post-boom income rebalancing – rather than by the contractionary

monetary policies in place in each case, and that are cited by most observers.10 This part of

Klein-Pettis’ argument recalls the stagnationist case in the final pages of the General Theory,

where John Maynard Keynes embraced a Marxian-like argument about the decline in the rate

of profit in mature economies.11 But the problem in the early 1930s was lack of demand

because of inadequate monetary reserves and constrained money supplies, not some secular

decline in opportunities for profit. And since the 2007-2009 Great Recession, central banks

have had trouble reaching their price inflation targets, and have fallen well short of what

reasonable targets might be for nominal GDP growth.

This sets up consideration of monetary and debt dynamics that Klein and Pettis perhaps intend

– but do not elaborate. The authors note that growing inequality is often accompanied by

growing debt ratios – and they cite evidence from the US in the 1920s.12 The premise is that

those with higher incomes did more saving, and -- relative to income – less consumption. More

recent evidence suggests that a savings glut at the top of the income and wealth pyramid in the

US is leading to growing indebtedness among the “lower 90 percent.”13 The problem, given

growing inequality, is that the only way consumption growth can keep pace with growth in

national income is by having higher-propensity consumers take on new debt – indeed by

increasing debt-to-national income ratios. By the same reasoning, were economic growth

9 Klein-Pettis (2020); p. 79-80. 10 For the Great Depression, see inter alia J.M. Keynes, Treatise on Money (1930); Ch. 37, Section iv.; H. Clark

Johnson, Gold, France, and the Great Depression, 1919-1932 (Yale, 1997); Scott Sumner, The Midas Paradox:

Financial Markets, Government Policy Shocks, and the Great Depression (Independent Institute, 2015). For Japan in

the 1990s, see Milton Friedman, “Reviving Japan”, Hoover Digest, 1998, No. 2.

https://www.hoover.org/research/reviving-japan 11 Keynes, General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936). Keynes does not mention Marx, but he does

suggest that the marginal efficiency of capital (ie, expected returns on investment,) might fall to close to zero; p. 375.

12 Klein-Pettis (2020), p. 81. 13 Rebecca Stropoli, “How the 1 Percent’s Savings Buried the Middle Class in Debt”, Chicago Booth Review, May 25,

2021. https://review.chicagobooth.edu/economics/2021/article/how-1-percent-s-savings-buried-middle-class-debt

Page 6 of 7

6

Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal (ASSRJ) Vol. 8, Issue 7, July-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

instead to be led by the lower 90 percent – by those with higher propensities to consume –

consumption could increase while the ratio of consumer debt to national income would decline.

Here is an added case for adopting policies that will lead to some redistribution of income and

wealth in the US and elsewhere.

Given current income distribution, savings patterns and capital flows pump up debt ratios, and

thereby increase financial fragility – that is susceptibility to financial default and instability. If

this conclusion is correct, it raises concern that monetary expansion under conditions of high,

or growing, income inequality will have a cost in generating financial breakdown – as Klein- Pettis believe it did in 2007-2008.

Getting back to inflation, my conclusion is that US government deficit spending is likely not to

be a separate factor boosting price increases now, or in the forseeable future. The world wants

to hold US government debt! My inference is that weak aggregate demand for the past decade

or more is, in part, a consequence of contractionary monetary policy on the part of the Federal

Reserve, the European Central Bank (ECB) and other central banks. A bit of inflation, perhaps

consistent with the Fed’s current AIT guidelines, might be a necessary (or, at least, collateral)

complement to boosting demand.

IOER AND DEFLATION

Understanding current monetary policy requires a moment of attention to the consequences of

paying interest on commercial bank deposits (that is, excess reserves,) held at the central bank.

The Federal Reserve, ECB and Bank of England now operate with “floor” systems, rather than a

corridor system, for guiding overnight interest rates.14 In a corridor system, the unsecured

overnight market rate (called the fed funds rate in the US) is higher than whatever interest rate

banks can earn by placing funds on reserve at the central bank. In a floor system, the interest

rate on excess reserves (IOER) is as high or higher than the fed funds rate. The difference

between the market rate and the central bank rate is the “corridor.” The Federal Reserve had

used a corridor system since its founding in 1913; it began to pay interest on excess reserves

(IOER) at a level as high as or higher than the fed funds rate only in October 2008, thereby

collapsing the corridor into a floor system. The fed funds market, which used to be the venue

for banks to meet their reserve requirements on a day-to-day basis, is now much shrunken.

Banks can earn as much or more by placing reserves with the Fed as they can by lending funds

to other banks – all with zero credit risk and no monitoring of interbank counterparts.

The Federal Reserve balance sheet grew from less than $1 T in 2008 to about $8 T in May 2021,

after nearly doubling during the pandemic from March 2020. The gross increase reflects

“quantitative easing” (QE) – the Fed’s aggressive open-market purchase of treasury and agency

securities. But most of the increase in central bank assets has been matched on the liability side

by increases in commercial bank deposits. Placing deposits at the central bank stops the reserve

multiplier (and hence monetary expansion) in its tracks; the impact on market liquidity of

placing excess reserves with the Fed is the equivalent of performing a central bank open- market sale – it is deflationary. What is the purpose of an open market purchase if it anticipated

14 George Selgin, Floored! How a Misguided Fed Experiment Deepened and Prolonged the Great Depression (Cato,

2018) is an outstanding reference on the topic.

Page 7 of 7

7

Johnson, C. (2021). Understanding Inflation Policy, 2021. Advances in Social Sciences Research Journal, 8(7). 1-7.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/assrj.87.10475

ahead of time that it will be offset by a commercial bank deposit at the Fed? Answer: it would

allow the Fed to change the maturity structure of the federal debt, for example by replacing 20-

year bonds held by the public with 6-month bills. Or it could replace treasuries in its own

portfolio with mortgage-backed or other agency securities – thereby giving a boost to the

mortgage-backed market.15

Consequences of the floor system have thus included giving the central bank a larger role in the

allocation of credit than was ever intended. In immediate context, the link between Fed balance

sheet management and monetary policy is more tenuous than it was before October 2008. By

most accounts, implementation of IOER slowed the recovery from the 2008 -2009 nadir.16

Indeed, it was presented in 2008 as a contractionary policy – a way to keep the fed funds rate

from sinking. (That was misguided; in October 2008, the US needed an expansionary monetary

policy to move beyond the financial crisis.) These consequences of the floor system have been

disappointing. The main reason central banks have maintained it appears to be that reducing

balance sheets to pre-October 2008 size would require them to take losses on their ever- growing inventory of government security assets.

What did not happen in 2008-2009, or more recently as we recover from the covid pandemic,

was a “helicopter drop” of new money. 17 The IOER rate has closely tracked rises and falls in the

effective fed funds rate over the last several years, meaning that much of the money injected

through from QE has been effectively withdrawn. Ongoing QE operations have led to increases

in narrow and broad money indicators, (as noted) including M4, despite the floor system. But

monetary policy will move into a truly expansionary mode if, and only if, quantitative easing

continues and the IOER is reduced to a level well below the market fed funds rate, thereby

restoring a corridor system. Restoring an active fed funds market would end the deflationary

mechanism implicit in IOER policy.

CONCLUSIONS

1. Central banks are able to target inflation rates without long lead times; the Federal

Reserve is capable of responding if, and when, unexpected price trends appear.

2. US current account deficits reflect excessive savings abroad, especially in China and

Germany, and consequent massive capital flows to the US. US government debt issuance

can provide securities demanded nationally and internationally, without inflationary

consequences.

3. The Fed’s current operating method – use of a floor system for interest rate management

– carries a deflationary bias that has slowed economic growth since its adoption in 2008,

and should be discontinued.

15 Ben S. Bernanke, The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis: Lectures by Ben S. Bernanke (2013). 16 Selgin (2018); pp. 90-91. 17 A “helicopter drop” has more technical definitions, but is generally an aggressive, deliberate increase in the quantity

of money. The reference is to a metaphor introduced by M. Friedman.