Page 1 of 20

Archives of Business Research – Vol. 9, No. 4

Publication Date: April 25, 2021

DOI:10.14738/abr.94.9521. Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in

The Global Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local

Enterprises in The Global Economy

OGBOR, John O.

Faculty of Management Sciences, Delta State University, Asaba Campus

Asaba Delta State, Nigeria

IYAMABHOR, Martins

Faculty of Management Sciences,

Department of Business Administration and Marketing, Delta State University

Asaba, Delta State, Nigeria

AWOSIGHO Onome Precious

Faculty of Management Sciences

Department of Business Administration & Marketing, Delta State University

Asaba, Delta State, Nigeria

ABSTRACT

As a result of the dynamics of globalization, the variegated economies of the world

have become more homogenous, integrated, interrelated and interdependent.

However, rather than becoming a veritable player in a network of interrelationship

and interdependency, the African economy has increasingly become a powerless

spectator in the theatre of globalization. Although there is a great deal of literature

and research in this area of international business, most of it has concentrated on

the multinational corporations and their effects on the host country’s economy.

Research and literature in this field have mainly looked at protective measures and

subsidies as the way out of foreign competition; it has rarely addressed competitive

strategic responses of local firms to foreign multinational corporations operating

in the local economies. Anchored on the resource-based view of the firm and the

network interaction theory, the paper provides an alternative framework or a

paradigm shift for analyzing the competitive options available to Africa’s local firms

in a global market. From this paradigm shift, the competitive advantages of Africa’s

local firms are conceptualized to be (i) a function of firm specific assets and (ii) the

prevailing home market conditions. The method of inquiry adopted in this paper is

textual deconstruction. The major contribution of this study to the existing

globalization discourse is its shift of focus from the multinational corporation to the

analysis of global competition from the perspective of the competitiveness of

enterprises in less developed economies such as Africa. The suggested framework

and paradigm shift can also be used by scholars to map strategic options for local

enterprises in selected markets. Future research can subject the suggested

framework to empirical scrutiny to see how well the arguments hold.

Keywords: Global economy, Globalization, MNCs, Competitive Advantage, Africa’s

Enterprises, Firm Specific Assets and Home Market Conditions.

Page 2 of 20

161

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

PREAMBLE: DAVID VERSUS GOLIATH - THE COMPETITIVENESS OF AFRICA’S

ENTERPRISES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

In 1Sam 17, the Hebrew Bible recounts the heroism of a bold young boy named David who fights

against Goliath, a Philistine giant. Even though he is untested, David defeats his experienced

and somewhat cocky opponent.

Seen from the angle of strategic management and especially in the context of firms’ competitive

advantage, the story has some implications for how small companies can compete and defeat

larger multinational enterprises in the battle field known as “the global economy” where firms

must fight (compete) with each other in order to conquer markets. In the field of marketing, it

is about how small companies with limited resources can use guerilla marketing tactics to

capture terrains already occupied by much larger firms. In this biblical narrative, we see Goliath

in terms of the more experienced Western and Southeast Asian countries of India, China

(formerly known as the “Sleeping Giant”), Japan and the “Four Asian Tigers” (i.e., the economies

of Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan).

The story of “David and Goliath” and how the little Israelite had defeated the giant champion of

the Philistines is by design, not by chance. David knew what his strengths were. David didn’t

play Goliath’s game. He played his own game. Collectively, these Western Power Houses and

their Southeast Asian counterparts are the giants in the theatre of the global economy.

Collectively, too, they dictate the rule of competition (the battle rules) in the global economy

(the battle terrain). They not only dictate the rules; they also enforce them through global and

supra-national organizations established by them to regulate the conduct the process and

structure of the global economy. These giant institutions, such as the World Bank (WB), the

International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Trade Organizations (WTO), etc, are specifically

set up as instruments for global economic surveillance. The giant economies have the

competitive arsenal or resources at their disposal; they are equipped with the armor of

technology, with powerful multinational and global enterprises. Sometimes, they, like the giant

Goliath, can be as cocky opponents; their leaders describe African countries as “shit-holes” or

“good-for-nothing” economies; or else as products of “banana republics” (Chapman, 2009). “A

banana republic”, to be sure, is a small state that is politically and economically unstable as a

result of the domination of its economy by a single export controlled by foreign capital. These

countries, which occupy the lower level of the economic ladder, are in perpetual need of foreign

financial assistance to survive; they are not competitive as they have been written off as

dumping grounds for Western left-over.

Several critical scholars from the anti-globalization camp have noted that the purpose of the

globalization “project” is the attempt by Western economies to create an economic space where

everything should converge in the direction of the dictates of Western needs. The project is to

be carried out mostly by large scale Western-based organizations. For instance, Ogbor (2002a),

in his work, From Spectacle to Surveillance and the Making of the Global Subject, makes the case

that the globalization process culminating in the global economy requires large-scale

organizations to deliver mass products to mass markets, consumers, and publics. He argues

that one of the reasons for globalization’s expansion lies in the functional necessity for large- scale organizations to ensure their own survivability. The global economy and the globalization

process thus imply what Marcuse (1964) calls the “conquest and unification of opposites”. In

this attempt to unify the opposites by the “Goliaths” of the global economy, the weaker

Page 3 of 20

162

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

“opposites” (i.e., African economies), argues Ogbor (2002b, pp. 524-526) “become mere

spectator in the theatre of the global economy.”

The much smaller local firms in African are often described as the little “David” in the Hebrew

bible; they have a weak economic and financial base to compete in the global economy with the

giant multinational enterprises; they are small and will remain small due to insufficient

resources (human, financial, labor, infrastructure, technology, etc.). Till date, African

economies are known as producers of commodity products or raw materials, while the

economic giants in the US, Europe and Southeast Asia are manufacturers of finished products.

With the notable exception of very few companies (e.g., the Dangote Group and South African

owned power houses such as MTN, Shoprite, PEP stores and Multichoice DSTv.), African local

enterprises have been incapable in facing the competitive forces of the Western multinational

giants. For several decades, policy makers in Africa have been confronted with crucial

challenge, among several others, that is, “for how long will this continue? What strategic options

do African countries or its local firms have at their disposal to fight the economic giants and

perhaps conquer their ‘lost territories’”? Until David, the little Shepherd boy, arrived in the

scene, and by using the small weapon at his disposal and with great confidence (his faith in his

God), he aimed at where Goliath was most vulnerable. While interpreters of this narrative use

the story of David and Goliath for its underdog overtones (the little guys win), there are rich

subtleties of this biblical story that writers of all stripes can use. For example, David leaves

behind his armor when he fights the militantly attired Goliath. Where Goliath is heavily armed,

David had a home-made crude weapon in the form of a sling and a stone. David is modest, but

Goliath brags and taunts.

THE COMPETITIVENESS OF AFRICA’S FIRMS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

Research and contemporary studies on the competitiveness of Africa’s domestic firms in the

global economy has been accentuated in recent years. This growing interest can be attributed

to the perceived disadvantageous position occupied by Africa in the globalization process or

“project”. In fact, some researchers have termed Africa’s participation in the global economy as

mere spectators in the theater of the process of globalization (Ogbor, 2002a). In line with this

reasoning, there has been an increasing interest and focus on the particular impact globalizing

processes has on the economies of developing nations, especially Africa. In one way or the

other, globalization has always affected Africa. Although, the ubiquitous global economy is seen

as beneficial to the economies of many parts of the world, African countries have palpably failed

to take advantage of the opportunities offered by the globalized economy of the twenty first

century: they receive little foreign investment, fail to produce many processed goods for export,

and are less “wired” than almost any other region of the world (Jensen, 1996; Ogbor, 2020;

Ogbor & Orishede, 2015a; Ogbor, 2015b; Ogbor, 2002a; Ogbor, 2002b).

But not all scholars or observers of the African economy in the context of global

competitiveness are satisfied with that type of explanation. Scholars sharing an optimistic view

argue that despite their overall poor performance, a few African nations are now poised to take

advantage of the new global economy while, at the other extreme, there are a significant

number of countries that are simply trying to preserve their basic institutions with little hope

of successful engagement with the world (Adeleye & Esposito, 2018; Amankwah-Amoah, 2018;

Ogbor & Orishede, 2015). From the point of view of these researchers, studies should focus on

what Africa’s enterprises have to offer in the global economy. This line of research draws its

Page 4 of 20

163

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

inspiration from the resource-based view of the firm____a theoretical framework that looks at

the resources at the disposal of firms. But, as Ogbor (2002a) puts it, what African economies

can offer in the present disposition is subjection to the dictates of the global economy.

Whatever the case may be, recent studies in the tradition of strategic management and firms’

competitiveness, are beginning to explore strategic options at the disposal of Africa’s local

enterprises in the global economy. In addition, there is a growing awareness that an

understanding of the forces shaping the competitiveness of Africa’s local enterprises in the

global economy could yield a whole lot of data capable of understanding why African economies

are subjected to the darker side of globalization. And there is more to it than that. By analyzing

the processes and structures of the global economy, scholars and policy makers will be moved

from the tradition of seeing Africa’s local firms as mere spectators in the globalization project

towards a position which digs into the deeper intricacies of how local firms can mobilize the

resources at their disposal to achieve competitive advantage.

In the discourse on globalization and the global economy, scholars and practitioners are by now

familiar with the general African economic situation that a comprehensive exposition is

unnecessary here. The continental performance has been poor: Africa overall has generally not

even returned to the economic peak of the late 1970’s when all natural resource prices were

relatively high. While the continent was experiencing the “lost decades” of the 1980’s and

1990’s, other regions were, of course, making spectacular gains.

From a comparative perspective, the differences in economic performance, according to Court

and Yanagihara (2012), can be found in manufactured export performance between Southeast

Asia and countries in Africa. According to the researchers, “the proportion of manufactures in

exports was relatively similar in Southeast Asia and Africa in 1970, in some cases African

countries were markedly better off. However, since then there has been a rapid and sustained

increase in the proportion of manufactured exports in all three countries in Southeast Asia. In

Africa, there has not been much increase except for Mauritius, where it was even more

pronounced than in SE Asia” (Court & Yanagihara, 2012). That the poor overall economic

performance of Africa in the global economy inevitably affects how Africa integrates into the

global economy is an understatement. While, for the most part, the African continent remains

a producer of relatively unprocessed raw materials, Asian countries have totally transformed

their industrial production becoming producers of consumer good.

There are many reasons for Africa’s poverty vis-à-vis other regions: the poor colonial

inheritance, especially in the area of dependence on the exportation of raw materials (Austin &

Chibuike, 2007; Moradi, 2008; Smith, 1994); crisis of governance and administrative

incompetence (Adams & Mengistu, 2008; Reynolds, 1995); poor policy implementation such as

the implementation of structural adjustment programs (Adam & O’Connell, 2006; 1997; Ogbor,

1994); .political instability and civil conflicts (Easterly & Levine, 1997; Ilorah, 2009; Pearce,

Islam& Sauvant, 1996); poor debt management and misallocation of financial resources

(Chipumbu, 1993); ethnic bias, bribery, corruption and favoritism (Fadahunsi & Rosa, 2002;

Ifediora, 2005); external circumstances (Ayenagbo, Wenguing, Rongcheng & Nguhi, 2012) and

poor policy implementation and institutional constraints (Ogbor, 1994).

Page 5 of 20

164

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

According to some analysts, the most serious barriers to Africa participating in the global

economy are (i) the dependency syndrome in raw material exportation and the concomitant

dependency in the importation of Western/Asian processed goods and (ii) the crisis of

governance. To be sure, “import and aid dependency syndrome” is an attitude and belief that a

group (e.g., a country or an economy) cannot solve its own problems without the importation

of goods and services or outside help such as financial assistance and grants.

The World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have a policy thrust whereby poor

and developing countries are recommended to adopt the policy instrument of export

promotion in which they are required to export more of their primary products that would help

them raise foreign exchange which is necessary for the repayment of their debts. However,

some observers have argued that this policy has worsened the competitive position of

developing and poor nations and deepened their dependency on the Western economies. Smith

(1994, p. 127) suggests that developed countries grow rich by selling capital-intensive products

for a high price and buying labor-intensive products for a low price. This imbalance of trade

expands the gap between rich and poor. The wealthy sell products to be consumed, not tools to

produce. This maintains the monopolization of the tools of production, and assures a continued

market for the product. This, according to Robbins (1999, p. 95), represents a type of

exploitation called unequal exchange.

Thus, one of the effects of the policy of structural adjustment is that developing countries must

increase their exports. Usually, commodities and raw materials are exported to Western

developed nations. But as Smith (1995) asserts, developing countries lose out when they export

commodities (which are cheaper than finished products) and are denied or effectively blocked

from industrial capital and real technology transfer. This economic policy reproduces and

reinforces a pattern of unequal development that favors the industrial economies to the

detriment of developing ones. Yet, this is not new, because as Ogbor (2009, p. 106) asserts,

Historically, this has been a partial reason for dependent economies and poor

nations to remain perpetually dependent on the dictates of the economies of the

developed nations. This was also the role forced upon former countries under

colonial rule. In today’s more globalized economy, we see the less developed

economies finding themselves in the same uneven pattern of trade: export

commodities to west and import finished products from the West.

The economic assumptions of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund had been

premised on the logic that exporting raw commodities and resources would favorably help

developing countries earn foreign exchange with which to pay off debts and keep currencies

stable. However, partly due to the price war, which can induce a situation where developing

countries produce more of raw materials, commodity prices have always dropped in the world

market relative to prices paid for manufactured products. In addition, Tan (2002) argues that

falling commodity prices have meant that large increases in export volume by commodity

producers have not translated into greater export revenues, leading to severely declining terms

of trade for many commodity producing countries. For example, when the purchasing power of

a country’s exports declines, the country is unable to purchase imported goods and services

necessary for its sustenance.

Page 6 of 20

165

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

Secondly, the country that exports commodities is unable to generate enough income for the

implementation of sustainable development programs. A vast majority of Sub-Sahara African

countries depend on the exportation of raw commodities as a main source of revenue. Tan

(2002) suggests that primary commodities account for about half of the export revenues of

developing countries and many developing countries continue to rely heavily on one or two

primary commodities for the bulk of their export earnings. Furthermore, a fall in commodity

prices has also led to a build-up of unsustainable debt. The consequence of all these is that

Africa, for the most part, has remained a consumer of manufactured products from the West.

As Ogbor (2009) puts it, an economic environment that encourages commodity export rather

than manufactured goods is hardly an environment for the growth of the local economy in the

context of industrialization.

In a nutshell, the above stream of research seems to suggest that what the IMF, the World Bank

and the developed countries recommended as solutions to the problems of developing

countries is contrary to what they had adopted in the process of their economic development.

As Smith (1994, p. 141) notes, every rich nation today has developed because in the past their

governments took major responsibility to promote economic growth. There was also a lot of

protectionism and intervention in technology transfer. There was an attempt to provide some

sort of equality, education, health, and other services to help enhance the nation. Smith (1994)

argues that the industrialized nations have understood that some forms of protection allows

capital to remain within the economy, and hence via a multiplier effect, help enhance the

economy. Yet, in the global economy and in the policies enshrined in the globalization process,

the developing nations are effectively being forced to cut back these very same provisions that

have helped the developed countries to prosper in the past.

As earlier pointed out, crisis of governance is seen as one of the obstacles militating against

Africa’s economic development in the context of the global economy. In general, African

countries lack the policy and legal frameworks to achieve sustainable economic development

and growth, although there are significant variations across the continent. It has been argued

by many observers that unless the governance issues are solved, Africa will not be able to

overcome all of the other problems that keep it from developing (Magbadelo, 2018; Makinda,

2012.).

In essence, the discourse on governance proposed eight principles or characteristics: (i) rule of

law, (ii) transparency, (iii) responsiveness, (iv) consensus oriented, (v) equity and

inclusiveness, (vi) effectiveness and efficiency, (vii) accountability and (viii) participation. The

uneven economic development pattern in most parts of Africa is explained against the backdrop

of the absence of these principles.

The summation of all the above factors, import dependence, governance or not, Africa’s local

enterprises have been gravely incapable of taking advantage of its local resources in order to

gain competitive advantage in the global economy. As pointed out earlier, the fundamental

challenge facing Africa’s economic development in the context of global competitiveness is:

what are the strategic options available to Africa’s local enterprises in the global economy and

what forms should those options take? To attempt answers to this question, we have to look

unto the theory of Resource-based view of the firm and the Network/Interactive Theory as

theoretical framework.

Page 7 of 20

166

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND OVERVIEW

The chosen framework for analyzing the competitiveness of Africa’s local enterprises in this

paper is an integration of contributions from the resource-based view of the firm (RBV) (Foss,

1997; Peteraf, 1993) and the network interaction theory of industrial marketing (Ford, 1990).

The RBV’s major point of departure is the assumption that the competitive advantage of firms

is based on the firm’s resource portfolio rather than the firm’s product market. It is based on

four basic assumptions. First, it assumes that there are systematic differences across firms in

the extent to which they control resources that are necessary for implementing strategies.

Second, these differences are relatively stable. Third, differences in firms’ resource

endowments cause performance differences. Lastly, firms seek to increase (maximize) their

economic performance. This framework suggests that firms may secure a strong performance

by building or otherwise acquiring certain endowments of resource: It draws attention to the

creation, maintenance and renewal of competitive advantage in terms of the resource side of

the firm.

For a firm’s resources to yield competitive advantage they should meet four basic criteria

heterogeneity, ex ante limits to competition, ex post limits to competition and imperfect

mobility (Peteraf, 1993). Heterogeneity means the resource must be rare for it to have

competitive advantage leading to efficiency differences and therefore rents. Ex ante limits to

competition suggest that resources have to be acquired at a price below their discounted net

present value in order to yield rents. Otherwise future rents will be fully absorbed in the price

for the resource. Ex post limits to competition suggest that it would be difficult or impossible

for competitors to imitate or substitute rent-yielding resources. Imperfect mobility suggests

that the resource should be relatively specific to the firm. Otherwise the superior bargaining

position that is obtained from not being tied to a firm can be utilized by the resource to

appropriate the rent that the resource helps create.

The resource based view theory of the firm predicts that resources at the disposal of the firm

are key determinant of firm performance. According to this view, such resources include the

firm’s core competencies in its marketing strategies, its production strategy, the uniqueness of

its location, distinctive human resource policies and practices, brand name/image, etc. In the

context of the global market or economy, local knowledge of societal norms, consumption

patterns, political culture, etc become resources within the array of resources at the disposal of

the firm. Properly utilized and managed, access to information, “right connections”, as firm’s

distinctive competence can provide the firm the basis upon which to achieve competitive

advantage in its industry.

The resource based view of the firm assumes sustainable competitive advantage as the desired

outcome of management effort (Fahy & Smithee, 1999). The nature of a firm’s sustainable

advantage, according to this theory, is obtained through accumulation and utilization of

valuable resources that are difficult to duplicate by competitors (i.e., imitability). Collis and

Montgomery (1995) suggest that sustainable competitive advantage can be created on

condition that resources have the attributes of inimitability, durability, appropriability,

substitutability, and competitive superiority. In essence, the theory suggests that unique, high

value and rare organizational resources lead to superior performance through enhanced

competitive advantage.

Page 8 of 20

167

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

The Resource-based view of the firm is an appropriate theoretical consideration in terms of its

applicability to competition in the global marketplace. The reason is that in the global

marketplace certain resources may be specific to a particular firm, while others may be generic.

For example, in the context of global competitiveness, a generic resource, e.g., technology or

production process alone may not be able to enhance the competitiveness of a firm over time

because rival firms may be able to easily copy them through a process of reengineering.

However, knowledge of the local business culture (specific resource) in combination of

technological knowhow may provide a valuable resource; hence the normative appeal from

proponents of competitiveness of firms in the global economy to go glocal. By paying attention

to the particular attributes in regions or countries while using global competitive strategies, the

term, “glocal”, was formulated to encompass the global attributes of a firm (such as technology)

and the localized idiosyncrasies in the markets where firms operate (Menon, 2014). The

process by which firms compete with uniform global strategies while paying attention to local

sensibilities is known as “Glocalization” which encourages companies to “think global, act

local”. As pointed out by Tashakova (2015), while glocalization was coined to describe how

multinational corporations can tap into local markets, it can also be used to describe how local

businesses can grab market share in their regional economies, and potentially, end up going

global themselves.

Resource-based view theory suggests that firms possess heterogeneous resources that allow

managers to execute value creating strategies. Even though it provides managers with a

decision making framework, the theory has been criticized for failing to consider the impact of

dynamic business and market environment (Odhiambo, Kibera & Musyoka, 2015) in which

many firms operate. Besides, the theory fails to explain how resources are developed and

deployed to achieve competitive advantage (Priem & Butler, 2001). This criticism emanated

from the dynamic capabilities theory. Teece, Pisano & Shuen (1997, p. 513) define dynamic

capability as “the ability to integrate, build, and reconfigure internal and external competencies

to address rapidly-changing environments”.

In this paper, we use the social networks and interaction theory as a complementary

perspective to the resource based view of the firm to study how firms can gain competitive

advantage in the marketplace, whether global or local. Social network theory is based on the

assumption that social relations are the key to explaining both individual action and collective

outcomes. Networks may be defined as bounded sets of actors, be they organizations,

institutions, or individuals that are connected by specific relationships (Ferreira, Serra &

Santos, 2010).

Over the years, studies have shown that organizational performance can be linked to the nexus

of social networks and interaction that organizations built up with its external stakeholders

(Aldrich, 1999). Organizations make use of their networks of interaction, especially when facing

intense competition (Gulati, 1998). How firms deploy their strategies to react (adjust) or to

undertake a pro-active action is one of the foci of strategic management research. For instance,

firms may acquire other organizations to access knowledge not yet held (Ferreira, 2005), enter

into an alliance to access new markets (Contractor & Lorange, 1988) or generally seek new

opportunities beyond their immediate competitive landscape through network forms of

organization (Gulati, 1995, 1998). All these strategic actions can be facilitated through the

network of relationships organizations have built in their immediate or remote environment.

Page 9 of 20

168

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

The extant literature has examined the importance of social networks for firms’ success (Dyer

& Singh, 1998; Gulati, 1995, 1998; Tenkasi & Chesmore, 2003), and more generally on a variety

of firms’ economic behaviors (Granovetter, 1985). These relationships form structures that are

capable of influencing firms’ strategic behavior, including their competitive strategies, by

promoting or constraining their access to information, physical, financial and social resources,

such as power and legitimacy (Baum, Calabrese, & Silverman, 2000; Gulati, 1998; Mohrman,

Tenkasi & Mohrman, 2003; Rowley, 1997).

From the perspective of this present study, the network/interaction theory views a firm as a

node in an ever-widening pattern of interactions with various stakeholders. The basic

assumption in this approach is to view the firm as a system of resources interacting with the

environment for its own survival. The competitiveness of a firm is determined by its ability to

procure resources from the network and not merely by the resources it owns. In a network,

customers, customer’s customer, suppliers, supplier’s suppliers, distributors, financiers’ etc.

are linked to each other by direct or indirect relationships.

Thus, the social network/interaction theory complements the resource-based view of the firm

by extending the firm’s resource profile to include the established networks and relationships

to various stakeholders. To fit in the RBV, these network relationships that are of significance

to competitive advantage are those that are valuable, rare, and not easy to be built or imitated

by competitors.

STRATEGIC OPTIONS AVAILABLE TO AFRICA’S FIRMS IN GLOBAL COMPPETITION

Having examined the theoretical perspective upon which this study is based, we now turn to a

discussion of the strategic options available to Africa’s firms in the global economy and global

competition. The main argument here is based on the premises that strategic options available

to Africa’s local enterprise in the global market will be based on its firm specific assets, its

prevailing global industry structure, as well as its prevailing home market condition. These

options can be summed up into three main areas:

• To compete directly against global multinational companies (direct competition),

• To compete indirectly by identifying a niche market (indirect competition) and

• To co-operate with global firms by forming strategic alliances (co-operation with global

multinational companies).

Direct Competition: The first strategic option suggests that Africa’s local enterprise (ALEs)

facing global competition can choose to compete face to face with multinational companies

entering their domestic market. Rather than give way to the new foreign entrant, the local

enterprise can choose to stay independent and fortify its existing competitive assets to outplay

the foreign multinational company (Thompson, Strickland and Gamble, 2010). The ability of

African enterprises to compete and win against foreign multinational enterprises will depend

on their capabilities in either producing at prices lower than global competitors (low-cost) or

their capabilities in producing unique quality products (differentiation) that appeal to the taste

of the major market segment.

The option of direct competition is more feasible in global markets where the multinational

enterprises cannot utilize their global advantages or in areas where the local (African)

enterprise has superiority in particular firm specific assets (networks with important local

Page 10 of 20

169

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

distribution firms, institutions and government agencies), which are accompanied with

domestic market conditions.

Indirect Competition: For many local enterprises, competing against global companies may not

be feasible especially when considering the multinational companies’ superiority in technology

and size advantages. An alternative option for many African enterprises, especially the small

and medium ones is to avoid direct competition with global companies. Indirect competition

can take place in several ways (Dawar & Frost, 1999). First, local enterprises can avoid

competing with global companies by concentrating activities in fragmented industries. In

fragmented industries, large global companies cannot utilize their scale advantages and

therefore find it less economical to operate in such markets, thus leaving a gap that local

enterprises can fill. Thus, the success of a local enterprise depends on the chosen niche, its

capabilities and its firm specific assets.

Secondly, local enterprises can avoid direct competition against global multinational

enterprises by concentrating in those niches that are of little or no interest to the multinational

enterprises, such as customizing to individual users who are willing and able to pay a premium

rather than accept the standard version. Most global companies have built their operations

around the demands of affluent customers looking for a wide range of choices. Their expatriate

managers are used to air-conditioned offices and expensive residences that altogether raise the

costs of the multinational company’s operations in an African country and make it not feasible

for them to target the lower end of the market. Since African companies are capable of operating

at relatively low costs they can target this lower-end market which in most cases covers the

majority and avoid direct clash with global companies.

Thirdly, Africa’s local enterprises can take the advantage of having the presence of

multinational enterprises by supplying products that complement the MNCs’ offerings or adapt

them to local tastes. For example, many oil and gas MNCs in Nigeria are able to shorten their

value chain through outsourcing services to domestic oil companies. In the Nigerian oil and gas

industry, domestic companies are taking advantage of assets left behind by foreign operators

and using their experience to grow into local giants.

Fourthly, local enterprises can choose to avoid direct competition with global companies by

exporting to markets not tapped by global players. African enterprises can go beyond their

domestic markets and export to markets where their firm specific assets can reap added

revenue, scale economies and valuable learning experiences. Seeking markets that are similar

to their home base in terms of consumer preference, geographic proximity, distribution

channels, or government regulations can achieve this end. Africa’s small and medium size

enterprises, for example, can export to the US, European and Asian markets by targeting their

products to the African population in the Diaspora.

Cooperative strategies: Rather than compete with the large global companies, local enterprises

can choose to co-operate with global multinational companies. This could be in the form of long- term contracts, joint venture, collaboration agreement and licensing, franchising,

subcontracting, or even management contract or counter trade agreement. The local enterprise

can choose to co-operate with global companies by establishing long-term contracts with them

for the supply of material inputs or components to the global firms. These long-term contracts

Page 11 of 20

170

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

have a number of benefits to the local firm. First, they shelter the firm from risks. Secondly, they

significantly reduce its marketing costs.

Apart from contractual agreements, the local enterprise can merge with a global company to

form a new venture/company that is jointly owned by both parties. In this case the global

company will accept this option only if it finds that there is something to gain from the joint

venture (examples of such joint ventures include, Hilton and Sheraton hotels operating in

Nigeria). It is, therefore, important that the local enterprise first understand the global

company’s motives for accepting to form the joint venture. If the motive of local enterprise is to

acquire knowledge from the global firm, it should prepare a mechanism for acquiring that

knowledge, that is, it should carry out a systematic investigation of inter-partner learning

(Hamel, 1991).

Local African firms can enter into a joint venture with the global company for the purpose of

developing risk-sharing mechanisms on new products and markets. By joining a global

company it can gain access to the global company’s international market network. This will

enable it to gain international experience and greater exposure to foreign markets and other

advantages of large corporation without losing identity and flexibility.

Other forms of co-operation such as licensing and franchising may the fastest ways for African

local enterprises becoming active players in the global economy (Tallman & Yin, 2002). These

arrangements are useful for local enterprises that lack technological know-how as assets.

Franchising on the other hand is a very useful method of gaining knowledge assets especially

in the area of production, management and marketing skills. By becoming a franchisee, the

African firm gets access to the knowledge assets that have taken the franchiser a very long time

to build.

FIRM SPECIFIC ASSETS AND THE COMPETITIVENESS OF AFRICA’S ENTERPRISES

There are several sources of sustainable competitive advantage. Competitive advantages that

are most significant are those that are specific to the enterprise’s unique bundle of tangible and

intangible resources. These resources can be distinguished as market assets, knowledge assets,

social assets and physical assets.

Market assets are mainly based on the enterprise’s established relationships with customers

and distributors through different kinds of interactions. The enterprise’s relationship with

customers and distributors becomes a strategic market asset only when the relationship has a

specific tie to that particular enterprise. These special relationships with different actors in the

market facilitate the enterprise’s product to reach customers in a unique way that adds more

value to the customer. A local enterprise’s long term interaction with local customers, for

example, creates customer loyalty (e.g. Nestlé’s Nescafe, Unilever’s Lipton, Nestlé’s Milo).

Customer loyalty generates resource position barriers against incoming competitors. Foreign

competitors entering the market will therefore have to pay a much higher price to win customer

loyalty. Just by the possession of these market assets the local enterprise therefore gains a

competitive advantage over any new company entering its domestic market.

Access to efficient distribution networks is often critical for any company to succeed in less

developed country markets. Market assets are path dependent, they are not easily achieved but

Page 12 of 20

171

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

when established they are not easy for competitors to break or replicate. Some Nigeria’s local

enterprises such as the Dangote Group, that have developed strong market assets are in a much

better position to compete directly against global competitors. One of the key firm specific

assets that are likely to determine the success of local enterprises competing directly with the

global company is their existing stock of market assets. More importantly, there are the

established networks that a company has with distributors and agents that are crucial for the

product’s success in the domestic market.

African domestic enterprises with well-established network across the nation may be able to

frustrate global multinational companies by making it difficult for them to reach target

customers. This is more valid in African countries where most markets are characterized by

having very few distributors who are capable of handling large stocks in an efficient manner. If

the enterprise has succeeded in tying these distributors in a way that competitors do not have

access to them; new foreign firms entering these markets may not be able to utilize the same

channels and thus prevented from reaching target customers. In Nigeria, for example, Nigerian

Breweries Limited has succeeded in competing directly against foreign firms (e.g., Budweiser)

by building a network of distributors and having exclusive agreements with a wide range of key

retailers across the country. Since there are very few reliable distributors in the market, new

foreign firms entering the market have had difficulty in getting access to consumers.

A strong local brand name (e.g., Glo, Maggi brand and OMO brand in Nigeria) is another market

asset that could enable the local enterprises competes directly against global competitors in the

domestic market, since brand names take time to build and once accepted customers become

loyal to that particular brand. For a foreign firm to overcome this, it may have to incur costs

that may not be sustainable, especially when considering the market size of most African

countries. Most African countries have very low purchasing power suggesting that

multinational companies may not be able to sustain their operations if the cost of building

brand names is too high. African enterprises can also use their market assets and networks of

interrelationships to negotiate strategic alliances with multinational enterprises with the aim

of gaining access to global markets or technological know-how.

Knowledge assets are based on the enterprise’s accumulated information, skills and know-how.

That is, to what extent is the local enterprise informed and knows how to exploit opportunities

and solve problems. Know-how is mainly embedded in individuals working for the enterprise.

Knowledge that is of relevance to strategic advantage is tacit knowledge; it is normally

accumulated after a period of learning. The question of how a company responds to a particular

problem or opportunity largely depends upon its combined competence of the individuals

(personalized knowledge) in the organization and or the knowledge stored (codified

knowledge) in the organization such as working manuals, structures, systems, processes,

drawings, prescriptions, culture, etc. Knowledge assets are the most important assets that are

likely to determine the competitive strength of the local enterprise.

Home country specific knowledge as an asset is one of the competitive advantages that Africa’s

local enterprises may have over incoming foreign competitors. Such edge gives the local

enterprise an advantage over foreign competitors because it cannot be easily acquired by the

foreign company due to compression diseconomies (Dierickx & Cool, 1989).

Page 13 of 20

172

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Successful local enterprises in Africa (such as Multi Choice of South Africa, Dangote of Nigeria,

Zenith Bank of Nigeria, Standard Chartered Bank of South Africa) that have succeeded in

operating in their home markets may have developed special knowledge assets, which are

specific to that particular home market. Such skills may be in the form of product technologies

or marketing know-how uniquely developed to fit well with specific consumer tastes, customs

and demands of the local consumer. Enterprises with such knowledge assets can use them to

compete directly against global multinational enterprises in those specific products or services.

Familiarity with the local tastes, for example, enabled Nigeria’s oldest brewer, Nigerian

Breweries Ltd., to maintain its presence in the Nigerian market despite the flow of global brands

(Budweiser) in the markets. The company’s specific knowledge of the local beer market,

modern managerial practices accompanied with in-house training of its sales force, enabled it

to develop low-cost, mass-market brands which managed to overcome rising competition from

imported beers.

Social assets of a firm are defined here as direct and indirect relationships that a firm has with

actors located in the non-market environment. This conceptualization of social assets is similar

to that of social capital (Paxton, 1999) and political behavior (Boddewyn & Brewery, 1994).

Social assets are specific ties that an enterprise has with individual members or groups within

the society. These ties may be reciprocal, trusting, and involving positive emotion. The nature

and context of these ties provide a basis upon which the enterprise can achieve strategic

objectives. A company’s special relationships with board members of a tendering company, for

example, are likely to enhance the company’s chance of winning the tender. Through social

interaction between the enterprise’s staff members and the tendering company’s board

member, additional clues and information that may be critical for the bidding enterprise

winning the tender can be revealed.

Social assets become a source of competitive advantage for local enterprises against global

companies in their domestic markets in a number of ways: First, acts of government, such as,

industrial policy can provide a conducive environment to the local enterprise’s competitive

advantage. Government policies may provide certain conditions that favor local companies or

restrict foreign owned companies in carrying out certain operations or access to certain

resources. Examples include ownership structure which is skewed against foreign ownership

and legislations requiring certain amount of local content in an industry’s value chain. Such

protection measures provide a competitive advantage over foreign firms that do not have

access to such resources or may have access to them at a higher cost.

Secondly, social assets do not necessarily require wealth. Protection measures that

discriminate foreign firms give the local firm a competitive advantage over foreign firms

without any cost. The fact that members of a society are ready to support a particular company

just because it is run by or employs members of their own ethnic group requires no prior

financial investment. This is the case of Globacom, a Nigerian-owned telephone service

providers competing against foreign-owned MTN, Airtel and Etisalat/9Mobile in the Nigerian

market. Globacom’s message that “it is owner own” resonates well among Nigerians who

consider themselves patriotic.

Thirdly, social assets are not easily accessible to a new foreign firm. Social assets are a result of

social interaction that takes time to build. The fact that a firm is local can encourage members

Page 14 of 20

173

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

of a community to be more loyal to that company, just because they trust their local company

is more committed than a foreign firm that is likely to leave any time. Local enterprises can

build on their social assets to compete directly with global multinational enterprises. By

establishing relationships with various stakeholders in the country, local firms can have access

to permits and exclusive rights that can be used to pre-empt foreign competitors entering their

domestic market. Multinational enterprises may enter the market but may be required to

operate at a higher cost relative to the local enterprises already established social assets. For

example, the multinational enterprise may have to spend more than average on advertising and

publicity just to match the competing local enterprise’s social assets.

Multinational companies that are willing to succeed in such markets where their domestic rival

has developed social assets may have to enter into collaborative arrangements so as to

guarantee access to the market This therefore puts the domestic enterprise at a competitive

position for bargaining a favorable deal in such collaborative arrangements. The question of

social assets was the main reason that led to the entering into a joint venture between local

African entrepreneurs and many foreign multinational companies. Such partnership

arrangements are mostly found in the oil and gas sector (NNPC and other multinational oil and

gas companies), accounting profession (Delloite & Touche, Accenture, KPMG, PwC), and in the

pharmaceutical industry (May & Baker, GlaxoSmithKline, Procter & Gamble).

Physical assets refer to the tangible resources that a company has and can be used to generate

additional revenue. Such resources may include capital equipment, manufacturing plant,

materials, land, building premises, financial resources etc. A firm’s access to physical resources

such as unique source of raw materials, high capacity plants can enable the firm to earn

economic rents based on those assets provided that they are not easily available to competitors

and they are not easy to substitute.

Local enterprises, especially those that were formerly state owned had exclusive physical

assets and are in a better position to compete directly against foreign competitors entering

their domestic markets. Some of these companies had capacities to produce large quantities

enough to meet the demand of an entire nation. Enterprises with such plants are capable of

creating entry barriers against foreign firms since it would be irrational for foreign firms to

enter a market where excess capacity would lead to intensive competition and low returns.

These local enterprises with such physical resources that require substantial amount of

investments may pre-empt foreign firms from incurring such investments.

HOME MARKET CONDITIONS AND THE COMPETITIVENESS OF LOCAL SMALL AND

MEDIUM SIZE FIRMS

The factor endowment theory of Hecksher (1919)-Ohlin (1933) ascribes differences in the

comparative advantage of countries in international trade to differences in factor endowment.

The fact that different countries have different factor endowments becomes a source of

competitive advantage for firms located in countries having lower cost factors to earn above

average economic rents. Resource rents arise due to differences of the cost of resources in a

particular country relative to other alternative sources. In areas where African countries have

relatively plentiful natural resources or low cost labor they are in a better position to provide

local enterprises with low-cost advantage against foreign companies. By their enterprises

Page 15 of 20

174

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

having access to low cost resources, they will be able to produce at lower cost than the global

industry and sell at international market prices.

In some countries, natural resources may be available at one particular location and therefore

giving a monopoly to the only one sole supplier. This is true in such industries as oil, mining

and power generation where the first mover advantage plays a crucial role. Small and medium

size companies in LDC having access to such resources can maintain their monopoly position

regardless of global competition. Local enterprises having access to such unique resources are

in a much better position to compete directly with global multinational enterprises.

These companies are also in a better bargaining position if they choose to cooperate with global

multinational enterprises as strategic partners. Due to their monopoly position they can choose

to co-operate with any multinational enterprise in exchange of market access or/and unique

technology that the multinational enterprises posses.

Local enterprises having access to low cost input sources are also in a better position in

competing directly with foreign firms entering their markets. They can capitalize on these cost

advantages by offering products at prices lower than the global multinational company. Since

most consumers in most countries in Africa are cost conscious, the African enterprise therefore

has a competitive advantage over the foreign firm that in most cases has additional cost to bear.

Most of the LDC does not have a very well developed infrastructure that allows easy access to

the whole national market. The infrastructure is characterized with inefficient distribution

systems, poor banking facilities, inadequate logistics; poor road networks, inefficient

telecommunication networks, and frequent power failures. This is far different from the

commercial infrastructure as is known in the West where the commercial infrastructure of

mails, dealers, distributors, multiple stores, credit cards, supermarkets and shopping malls is

normally taken for granted. Although the potential market may be large, access may require a

great deal of investment for a foreign firm from developed economies to be able to operate

efficiently in such markets. On the other hand, since the local firm has always been in this

environment it has already learnt to deal with it and is therefore compatible with such

infrastructural problems.

In such conditions local firms are likely to have a better competitive position than foreign

firms entering such markets. In several developing countries (e.g., Nigeria), producers and

distributors have worked for a substantial time, they develop trust to an extent that the

manufacturing enterprise keeps a supply of open cheques from their distributors. When the

manufacturing enterprise sends the order it simply fills in the respective amount based on the

shipment in the blank signed cheque. Thus, the absence of a viable financial infrastructure and

the lack of working capital have been overcome by trust built by the different actors in the

market after a long time of business interaction. Local firms that have learnt to overcome such

infrastructural impediments can therefore use this experience to compete directly with global

multinational enterprises entering their domestic markets with no prior experience in

operating in such environments.

African enterprises with such experiences can also use these experiences to enter other

developing countries with similar infrastructures, especially those markets where cultures are

Page 16 of 20

175

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

similar to those of the home market. Due to the fact that the majority of the population in Africa

has very low income, domestic demand is constrained by very low purchasing power. The

middle class that can afford higher prices is very small. The majority of the population is

concerned with meeting the basic necessities. Most African consumers look for products that

are durable, have lower prices and lower maintenance costs. As a result of this, consumers in

African countries are far more focused on the price-performance equation than their

counterparts in developed economies.

These demand conditions tend to give local low-cost African enterprises a much better

competitive position in hotly contested markets. Foreign firms will either have to target the

very small middle class or sell at the lower prices on a cash basis, an option that may not be

feasible to foreign firms. Many foreign firms have rushed into developing countries being

attracted by the market size, only to realize that the costs are much higher than the profits that

they are likely to get from operations in such markets. Africa’s small and medium size

enterprises can capitalize on local demand conditions and compete directly with global multi- national enterprises by targeting the lower end of the market where the majority of consumers

are located. Nigerian Breweries Limited, for example, has managed to capitalize on domestic

demand conditions in Nigeria by pursuing aggressive marketing strategies by offering products

to all market segments thus leaving very little room for any foreign company to dominate the

market. Nigerian Breweries Limited offers low priced quality beer to the mass- market segment

of low-income earners. At the same time, it offers other brands at premium prices targeting the

small upper niche where it competes with other global brands such as Heineken and Guinness.

CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS

As a result of globalization, the world market has become more and more integrated and African

enterprises are increasingly being exposed to vagaries of global competition. The growing

literature in international business has assumed that globalization has put African enterprises

at a disadvantage vis-a-vis the large global companies. Based on the resource-based view of the

firm, this paper has provided an alternative framework for analyzing the competitive options

available to African local enterprises in a global market. The framework suggests that firm

specific assets, global industry conditions and the local enterprise’s home market will influence

competitive options for African enterprises.

Through a meta-synthesis of the available discourse and counter discourse of Africa’s

competitiveness in the context of the global economy, this paper has argued that by drawing

strength from their firm specific assets, Africa’s local enterprises, as our biblical “David”, can

stand up and compete against global companies (the Goliaths) entering their domestic markets,

particularly in multi-domestic industry structures where pressures for globalization are low.

African local enterprises can also avoid direct confrontation with large global companies by

choosing to serve niche markets that require firm specific assets or in fragmented markets that

are not attractive to global companies. The option of collaborative arrangements with global

companies will enable them to gain market access and learn from global companies.

To the field of international business management this study has started the shift of focus from

the multinational enterprise to the analysis of global competition from the perspective of the

competitiveness of enterprises in less developed countries such as African countries. The

suggested framework can also be used by scholars to map strategic options for local enterprises

Page 17 of 20

176

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

in selected markets. Future research can empirically test the framework to see how well the

arguments hold.

To policy makers, the discussion provided in this paper goes beyond protectionism and opens

up alternative views of the role that local companies can play in the global market. It encourages

policy makers to provide incentives for the empowerment of their national enterprises without

necessary going against the World Trade Organization (WTO) rules. Both foreign as well as local

enterprises can grow for mutual benefit of all parties.

For managers of local enterprises, this work provides a useful contribution to changing their

mindset from that of weak players to that of veritable competitive players in the global markets.

This study has highlighted areas of strength which local firms can capitalize on to build their

competitive advantages in global markets.

References

Adam, & O’ Connell, S (2006). Monetary policies and aid management in Sub-Saharan Africa. Unpublished paper,

Oxford, UK: University of Oxford and Swarthmore College.

Adams, S., & Mengistu, B. (2008).Privatization, Governance and Economic Development in Developing Countries.

Journal of Developing Societies, 2, 415-438.

Adeleye, I & Esposito, M. (2018). Africa’s Competitiveness in the Global Economy. AIB

Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) Series. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Agmon, T. & Drobnick R. (1994). Small firms in global competition. Oxford University Press

Aldrich, E. (1979). Organizational environment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Austin, Gareth (2010). African Economic Development and Colonial Legacies, International Development Policy 1,

11-32.

Austin, Gareth, and Chibuike Ugochukwu Uche (2007). Collusion and competition in colonial economies: Banking

in British West Africa, 1916-1960. Business History Review, 81(1), 1-26.

Bangens, Lennart (1998). Interfirm linkages and learning: an empirical exploration of firms in the third world.

Goteborg: Chalmers University of Technology.

Baum, J., Calabrese, T., & Silverman, B. (2000). Don't go it alone: alliance network composition and startups’

performance in Canadian biotechnology. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3), 267-294.

Bergh, A & Nilsson, T. (2010). Do liberalization and globalization increase income inequality?

European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 488-505.

Boddewyn, J. & Brewer, T. L. (1994). International-business political behaviour: new theoretical directions.

Academy of Management Review, 19(1), 119-143.

Brennan, L. & Garvey, D. (2009). The role of knowledge in internationalization. Research in International Business

and Finance 23 (2009), 120–133.

Chapman, Peter (2009). Jungle capitalists: a story of globalization, greed and revolution. Edinburgh, New York:

Canongate.

Chipumbu, G. M. (1993). The Impact of external debt on African economies. International Journal on World Peace,

10(1), 43-56.

Collier, P. (1995). The marginalization of Africa, International Labour Review. 134(5), 47-62.

Collis, D. J., & Montgomery, C. A. (1995). Competing on resources: Strategy in the 1990s, Harvard Business Review,

July-August, 118-128.

Page 18 of 20

177

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

Contractor, F., & Lorange, P. (1988). Cooperative strategies in international business. Lexington, MA: Lexington

Books.

Court, J. & Yanagihara, T. (2012). Asia and Africa into the global economy: Background and Introduction.

Retrieved from http://archive.unu.edu/hq/academic/Pg_area4/August-intro.html (January 21, 2020).

Dawar, N. & Frost, T (1999). Competing with Giants: Survival Strategies for Local Companies in Emerging

Markets. Harvard Business Review, March-April Issue.

Dyer, J., & Singh, H. (1998). The relational view; cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational

competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4), 660-679.

Dierickx, I. & K. Cool. (1989). Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage. Management

Science, 35, 1504-14

Easterly, W. & Levine, R (1997). Africa’s growth tragedy: politics and ethnic division. Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 112, 1203-50.

Fadahunsi, A & Rosa, P. (2002). Entrepreneurship and Illegality Insights from the Nigerian cross-border Trade.

Journal of Business Venturing, 17(5), 397-429.

Fahy J. (1998). The Role of Resources in Global Competition. In G. Hooley, R. Loveridge and D. Wilson (eds.)

Internationalization. The Academy of International Business Series. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Fahy, J. & Smithee, A. (1999). Strategic Marketing and the Resource Based View of the Firm. Academy of

Marketing Science Review, 10, 1-18.

Ferreira, M. P. (2005). Building and leveraging knowledge capabilities through cross border acquisitions: the effect

of the MNC's capabilities and knowledge strategy on the degree of equity ownership acquired. Unpublished doctoral

dissertation, University of Utah, Salt Lake City, UT, USA.

Ferreira, M. P., Serra, F., & Santos, J. (2010). The international entrepreneurial firms’ social networks. Cadernos

Ebape, 8(1), 133-145

Ford, D. (1990) Understanding Business Markets. Interaction, Relationships, Networks. London: Academic Press.

Foss, Nicolai J. (1997). Resources, firms and strategies: a reader in the resource-based perspective. London: Oxford

University Press.

Gulati, R. (1998). Alliance and networks. Strategic Management Journal, 19(4), 293-317.

Gulati, R., & Gargiulo, M. (1999). Where do interorganizational networks come from? American Journal of

Sociology, 104(5), 1439-1494.

Håkanssons, H. (1982). International marketing and purchasing of industrial goods. An interaction approach.

Chichester: John Wiley.

Hamel, Gary (1991). Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within international strategic

alliances. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12, 83-103

Heckscher, E. (1919). The effect of foreign trade and the distribution of income, Economist Tidskrift, 21.

Ifediora, J. (2005). The Effects of Bureaucratic Corruption on Economic Development:

The Case of Sub-Saharan Africa. Retrieved from www.nigeriavillagesquare1.com/Articles/Guest/. (February 23,

2020).

Ilorah, R. (2009). Ethnic bias, favoritism, and development in Africa. Development Southern Africa, 2(5), 695-707.

Jensen, M. (1996). Bridging the gaps in Internet development in Africa. Retrieved

from http//www.idrc.ca/acacia/studies/ir-gaps3.htm (April 9th, 2019)

Kobrin, S. J. (1991). An empirical analysis of the determinants of global integration. Strategic Management

Journal, 12, 17-31

Magbadelo, J. O. (2018). Governance and the crisis of rule in Africa: Leadership in transformation. African Affairs,

117(469), 711–732.

Page 19 of 20

178

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 9, Issue 4, April-2021

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Marcuse, H. (1964). One Dimensional-Man: Studies in the Idealogy of Advanced Industrial Society. New York, NY:

Beacon Press.

Makinda S.M. (2012). Africa’s Leadership Malaise and the Crisis of Governance. In: K. T. Hanson, G. Kararach, & T.

M. Shaw (eds.) Rethinking Development Challenges for Public Policy. International Political Economy Series.

London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Mohrman, S., Tenkasi, R., & Mohrman, A., Jr. (2003). The role of networks in fundamental organizational change.

The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 39(3), 34-52.

Moradi, A. (2008). Confronting colonial legacies: Lessons from human development in Ghana and Kenya, 1880-

2000.Journal of International Development, 20(8), 1107-21.

Odhiambo, O. J., Kibera, F. & Musyoka, R. (2015). The Influence of Organizational Culture and Marketing

Capabilities on Performance of Microfinance Institutions in Kenya. Journal of Marketing Management, 3(1), 91-

99.

Ogbor, J. O. (2020). The Making of the Global Subject: Discourse, Power and Subjection. The International Journal

of Business and Management, 8(3), 24-38.

Ogbor, J. O. & Orishede, F. (2015). Openness and Closure: The Dialectics and Contradictions of Globalization and

the Development of African Entrepreneurship. Journal of Social and Management Studies, 10(1), 44-54.

Ogbor, J. O. and Orishede, F. (2011). Structural Adjustment Programs in Africa: Dialectics and Contradictions.

Trend Journal of Management and Social Sciences, 4(2), 108-117.

Ogbor, J. O. (2002a). From Spectacle to Surveillance: The Making of the Global Subject, Business Research

Yearbook, VIX, 524-528.

Ogbor, J. O. (2002b). Understanding the Global Economy and its Competitiveness as Relations of Power, Journal

of Global Competitiveness, 10(1, 47-64.

Ogbor, J. O. (2009). Entrepreneurship in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Strategic Management Perspective, AuthorHouse,

Bloomington, Indiana.

Ogbor, J. O. (1994), Structural Adjustment and the Politics of Adjustment: The Nigerian Foreign Exchange,

Stockholm, Sweden: Norsdet.

Ohlin, Bertil (1933). Interregional and international trade. Cambridge: Mass: Harvard University Press.

Paxton, Pamela (1999). Is social capital declining in the United States? A multiple indicator assessment. American

Journal of Sociology, 105(1), 88-127

Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstone of competitive advantage: a resource- based view. Strategic Management

Journal, 14, 179-191.

Priem, R.L. & Butler, J.E. (2001). Is the resource-based view a useful perspective for strategic management

research? Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 22-40.

Porter, M. E. (1990). Competitive advantage of nations. London: Macmillan Press.

Robbins, R. (1999). Global Problems and the Culture of Capitalism. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Rowley, T. (1997). Moving beyond dyadic ties: a network theory of stakeholder influences. Academy of

Management Review, 22(4), 887-910.

Smith, J. W. (1994). The World’s Wasted Wealth 2. Cambria, CA: Institute for Economic Democracy.

Tallman, S. & Yip, G. S (2002). Strategy and the Multinational Enterprise. The Oxford Handbook of International

Business. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Tashakova, O. (2015). Going Glocal: Home Grown Brands Have Distinctive Advantage Over its Competitors in the

Market. Retrieved from https://www.entrepreneur.com/article/251609 (May 23, 2020).

Teece, D.J., Pisano, G. & Shuen, A. (1997), Dynamic capabilities and strategic management, Strategic Management

Journal, 18(7), 509-535.

Page 20 of 20

179

Ogbor, J. O., Iyamabhor, M., & Awosigho, O. P. (2021). David Versus Goliath: The Competitiveness of Africa’s Local Enterprises in The Global

Economy. Archives of Business Research, 9(4). 160-179.

URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.14738/abr.94.9521

Tenkasi, R., & Chesmore, M. (2003). Social networks and planned organizational change: the impact of strong

network ties on the effective change implementation and use. The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 39(3),

281-300.

Thompson, A. A., Strickland, A. J., & Gamble, J. E. (2010). Crafting and Executing Strategy: The Quest for

Competitive Advantage (17e). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Wernerfelt, Birger (1984). A resource-based view of the firm, Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171-80.

Wikstrom S. & Norman, R. (1994). Knowledge and value: a new perspective on corporate transformation. New

York: Routledge.