Page 1 of 20

Archives of Business Research – Vol. 13, No. 03

Publication Date: March 25, 2025

DOI:10.14738/abr.1303.18487.

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value

Delivery: An Application to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational

Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application to

Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria

Muritala Awodun

Centre for Enterprise and Human Capital Development

Crown-Hill University (now Ojaja University),

Eiyenkorin, Kwara State, Nigeria

Lukman Adam

Department of Economics, Faculty of Social Sciences

Kwara State University, Malete, Kwara State, Nigeria

ABSTRACT

In relating the agency theory to corporate governance and technological

disruptions in organizations, this paper examines this tripod through the creation

of an agency-governance-disruptions model. The paper relates the model to

operational efficiency, profitability and value delivery in selected private and

public enterprises in Nigeria. The outcome reveals that the tripod of agency- governance-disruptions, as presented through the model, significantly impacts on

operational efficiency, profitability and value delivery of organizations in Nigeria.

This is based on applying the model to selected private and public universities in

Nigeria, with the findings revealing that the agency-governance-disruptions model

has a very significant impact on the efficiency, revenue generation/profitability and

value delivery of the private universities, while for public universities, on the other

hand, the effects are not so significant.

Keywords: agency theory, corporate governance, technological disruptions, operational

efficiency, profitability, value delivery

INTRODUCTION

There are three main concepts involved in the derivation of our agency-governance-disruptions

model, and each of these concepts are worthy of description and understanding. This paper

presents each of the concepts with the intention of aggregating thoughts about them and taking

a position on why they are relevant in our model. The integration of these three concepts in

formulating our model is subsequently justified, and the relevance of each, in affecting the

fortunes of an organization, is measured through a look at operational efficiency, revenue

generation/profitability and value delivery. How our model affects different types of

organizations is extracted by applying the model to some selected private and public

universities in Nigeria.

The concept of agency theory as presented by Berle and Means (1932), Fama and Jensen

(1983a, 1983b); and Jensen and Meckling (1976) is directed at a particular type of organizing

problem, called agency problem (Eisenhardt, 1989). Agency theory models the relationship

between a principal and an agent, and considers the optimal contract form for the ubiquitous

Page 2 of 20

172

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

relationship where a principal, delegates work to an agent (Eisenhardt, 1989; Awodun, 2007,

2018). Agency theory is built on the notion that separation of ownership and control potentially

leads to self-interested behaviors by the agent. In agency theory, both the principal (i.e.,

shareholders, who are the owners of the enterprise) and the agent (i.e., managers of the

enterprise) are depicted as utility maximizers (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen

1983a). The agent’s utility function includes power, security, status, and wealth, while the

principal’s utility function is to maximize the market value of their shares, an ultimately, their

wealth (Awodun, 2018).

Corporate governance, on the other hand, is the process that guides the relationship between

the company and the stakeholders through the determination and control of the strategic

direction and performance of the company (Awodun, 2018). It is the system through which

organizations are directed and controlled towards achieving the purpose of their

establishment. This structure specifies the distribution of rights and responsibilities among the

various corporate participants, including board members, executives, shareholders and other

stakeholders, spelling out the rules and procedures for making decisions on corporate affairs

(Luo, 2005a). Corporate governance also provides the structure through which the company

sets objectives, the strategy for attaining those objectives and the guidelines for monitoring

performance (Awodun, 2007).

Governance contributes to the firm’s legitimacy and the credibility of its decisions and

reporting. In the context of private enterprises, corporate governance is the system that not

only monitors the relationship between executives and stakeholders (including shareholders),

but also directs its various business units and pinpoints the distribution of power, rights and

responsibilities among critical participants in the corporate-level decision-making process that

affects the general corporate affairs (Awodun, 2018). For the public enterprises, however,

corporate governance monitors the relationship between the managers of such enterprises and

the various stakeholders, including the executive arm of government, the legislative arm of

government and the citizens (in terms of value delivery).

Technological disruptions are seen as the convergence between new business models, new

technologies, and new combinations of existing approaches to create a competitive advantage,

such that one business is positioned to take market share away from other businesses through

better and improved performance. It affects both private and public enterprises differently, for

reasons of structural ownership, management and operational differences, and not for any

reason of technical divergence.

Technological disruption represents an increase in the use of machine-driven automation of

operational processes and workflows that were previously undertaken, or at the very least,

overseen, by humans. The introduction of technology, enables greater operational efficiency

and opens up opportunities to create new revenue streams, improve productivity, increase

profitability and ultimately, value delivery.

Disruption is all about adaptation to the alternative of using technology to replace what human

is doing, and is often discussed through the lens of outmaneuvering an incumbent, or

challenging the status quo. It is good to note that many private enterprises are successfully

Page 3 of 20

173

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

leveraging new technologies to adapt to new markets and evolve their offerings. They often have

the resources and are quicker to make larger investments into emerging technologies than their

public enterprises compatriots.

Technological disruption has been occurring since people first started trading goods and

services, and will continue for as long as we continue to innovate. Disruptions could come from

within the organization, which is called internal disruption. At the same time, disruption could

be as a result of technological changes from outside the organization, but within the market,

which is referred to as external disruption.

The above conceptual clarifications have given credence and understanding to the concepts that

make up our agency-governance-disruptions model. In the section that follows, we present a

review of literature by digging deeper into the basis of these concepts. Thereafter, we present

the model itself, with some further clarifications to the underlying factors that brought about

our conceiving it. We also, relate the model to private and public universities, as our

representation of private and public enterprises, in our attempt to measure the impact of the

model on the three variables of operational efficiency, revenue generation/profitability and

value delivery in these enterprises. Our findings and the analysis of these findings are presented

next. This is followed by our recommendations and conclusion, in that order, as the final analysis

of this paper.

LITERATURE REVIEW

In agency theory literature, the primary agency problems popularly referred to are moral

hazard (MH) and averse selection (AS) (Eisenhardt, 1989). MH is a problem resulting from the

situation where the principal cannot observe or monitor the agent’s actions. Arrow (1985, p.

37) says that the problem here arises when “the agent’s action is not directly observable by the

principal.”

Averse selection (AS), on the other hand, is a problem resulting from the situation where the

principal can observe the agent’s actions, but cannot assess whether these actions best serve

the principal’s interests. Arrow (1985, pp. 38-39) opined that the problem, in this situation,

arises when “the principal may be able to observe the action itself, but does not know whether

it is the most appropriate one.”

According to Mitnick (1994), the critical difference between MH and AS is that in MH the

principal cannot observe the agent’s actions, allowing the agent to take actions that have

undesirable consequences for the principal, while in AS, the principal may well be able to

observe the agent’s actions, but the principal cannot tell whether the agent’s actions are optimal

with respect to the principal’s interests or not (Awodun, 2018). Thus, it is quite conceivable

that agency problems could be aggravated if it becomes more difficult for the principal to

observe and judge what the agent is actually doing and has done for the principal. Both are

predominantly of more concern in public enterprises than in private enterprises for obvious

reasons.

Agency theory is considered appropriate to situations that have a principal-agent structure.

Specifically, in the case of private enterprises, the headquarters-foreign subsidiary relationship

Page 4 of 20

174

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

in multinational enterprises can be considered a good example of a principal-agent structure,

since the headquarters delegates decision-making authorities and responsibilities to foreign

subsidiaries (Gupta and Govindarajan, 1991; Nohria and Ghoshal, 1994; Roth and O’Donnell,

1996). Beyond this, the shareholders, who are the owners of the private enterprise, constitute

the principal, and delegate authority to the management of the private enterprise, in this

situation seen as the agent, to operate the enterprise on their behalf, and in their interest.

The extent of difficulty to which the principal (i.e., the shareholders or the public as the case

may be) faces in the observation and verification process could be dependent upon the strategic

roles of the agent (i.e., the board and management of the enterprise). Just like in the case of

multinational enterprises where the foreign subsidiaries face different levels of agency

problems in their relationship with the headquarters depending on the strategic role they are

undertaking – i.e., specialized contributors, local implementers, and world mandates (Kim et al.,

2005), the public enterprises are not different in their exhibition of different levels of agency

problems also.

Another critical question often omitted from the discussion on corporate governance is the

scale of operations of some major private or public enterprises. The very fact that some large

multinational firms, for instance, have annual turnover exceeding the budget expenditure of

developed national economies such as Belgium, or Italy in Europe and virtually all African

countries, suggests that the scale of coordination and control within a multinational enterprise

will be as complex as what exists at the level of co-ordination and control of economic activities

within some nation states (Todeva, 2005).

There is the need to examine the significant implicit and common understanding of some

concepts that derive mainly from agency theory. Major among these are transaction cost

economics and stakeholders’ theory.

The agency theory substantiates most of these arguments on efficient governance. Considering

that the corporation is a bundle of contracts, the contract between managers and shareholders

is not different from the contracts between the other agents involved in the value-adding

activities (employees, customers, suppliers). Investors as owners of stock in the stock market

capitalism, delegate decision-making powers to agents (managers and independent directors).

Ultimately, agency costs rise not only because of opportunistic behavior by managers, but also

from the monitoring and control mechanisms put in place by stock-holders (Awodun, 2018).

The entire corporate governance system, put in place to protect investors’ interest, represent

an institutionalization of monitoring and control procedures, raising costs, and diminishing

allocative efficiency (Otokiti, 2007) in most cases, particularly in public enterprises.

In mature market economies, where contract enforcement is undertaken by the state,

monitoring and control costs are shared between the MNE and state institutions. The costs of

corporate governance, however, remain at corporate level, reducing the value-added and the

wealth, created by the corporation. For MNEs operating in underdeveloped market economies,

risks from opportunistic behaviour at remote locations add additional agency costs that have

to be absorbed by the multinational, and hence multiple risk-sharing initiatives are undertaken,

all eroding the profits from these international operations.

Page 5 of 20

175

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

Hill and Jones (1992) summarise three sources of agency costs from the perspective of agency

theory as: (a) principal’s monitoring expenditure; (b) agents’ bonding expenditure; and (c)

residual loss.

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AS A PRODUCT OF AGENCY THEORY

Corporate governance, the centerpiece of our model, is a product of the agency theory, and it

refers to a process of supervision and control over company management, involving a system

of external and internal checks and balances that ensures companies discharge their

responsibilities in an accountable manner to stakeholders (Tricker, 1984; Cannon, 1994;

Parkinson, 1994; Solomon and Solomon, 2004). It is a system/mechanism for allocation of

resources, control and co-ordination of economic activities at firm level that facilitates strategic

direction, accountability, transparency and wealth creation (Awodun, 2007; Otokiti, 2007).

Components of Corporate Governance

The first component of market-based corporate governance is ownership concentration, which

is defined by the number of large-block shareholders (i.e., mutual funds, pension funds and

trust funds), as well as by the proportion of shares they own. These institutional owners

become increasingly active in their demands that corporations adopt effective governance

mechanisms to control managerial decisions (Lorsch, 1989). Ownership concentration by a

small number of large-block shareholders can improve governance effectiveness because it

strengthens shareholders’ power when dealing with management (Mizruchi, 1983).

The higher the degree of ownership concentration, the more likely manager’s strategic

decisions will mesh with shareholder value maximization (Tihanyi et al., 2003). Moreover,

while company stock ownership can encourage wealth-maximization behaviour among

managers, Igbal and French (2007) argue that ownership allows entrenchment of managers

who own a large enough stake to reduce the possibility of their dismissal. This they referred to

as manager-entrenchment hypothesis.

Second, board composition, or the proportion of “inside” directors (executive directors) vs.

“outside” (non-executive directors), also has strong implications on corporate governance

because the board is essentially the “guardian” of the principal’s interest. Thus, many believe

that effective boards should be composed of greater proportions of outside directors (Mizruchi,

1983; and Borokhovich et al., 1996) because outside directors can make more exhaustive and

profound evaluations of strategic decisions and management behavior than inside directors

(Baysinger and Butler, 1985).

Market discipline is a third component of market-based corporate governance; it is an external

mechanism that becomes active when a firm’s internal controls fail, its performance is poor

and/or its management is ineffective. Market discipline may involve replacing incompetent

CEOs, other key executives and/or board members, or it can come in the form of a takeover

(especially hostile one) by another corporation. Under a hostile stakeholder, both key

executives and board members may be replaced by new management and new directors (Fama

and Jensen, 1983; Baysinger and Butler, 1985).

Page 6 of 20

176

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Fourth, board chairmanship involves whether or not a firm’s CEO is also the board of directors’

chairperson. Where the influence of the CEO is strong on the board, whether as chairperson or

not, feelings of loyalty or responsibility towards the CEO may restrict the directors’ freedom

and independence to make difficult and contrary decisions (Singh and Harianto, 1989).

Fifth, board size is an important factor of market-based corporate governance since there are

drawbacks when boards are either too small or too large. There should be some sort of

moderation in sizing of board of directors.

Six, management remuneration as a market-based governance mechanism can be either

behavior-based or outcome-based (Eisenhardt, 1989). When managerial behaviors are well

understood, and evaluated, a behavior-based scheme is generally more appropriate. In such a

scenario, the agent receives a fixed wage for taking well-defined actions and penalizes him or

her for taking sub-optimal actions.

When managerial behaviors are not well-defined, outcome-based compensation plans that

reward the agent’s performance instead of actions are preferred. Despite differences in

compensation standards across countries, it is generally agreed that (1) executive

remuneration should reflect executive responsibilities; (2) remuneration should be reasonable

and comparable with market standards; and (3) incentive schemes should be clearly linked to

performance benchmarks (Tosi and Gomez-Mejia, 1989; Davis et al., 1997).

A seventh element in market-based corporate governance is a widely-used practice whereby

two or more companies exchange board members; this is known as interlocking directorate.

However, from the agency cost perspective, interlocking directorate may obstruct decision- making independence and transparency because under-performing managers who maintain

good personal ties with their interlocking partners may stay on their jobs (Zajac, 1988). Finally,

inbreeding is a practice whereby senior executives join the board after retiring from

management. This has its advantages and disadvantages on the organization, but the former

seems to outweigh the latter.

Market-based governance mechanisms are considered necessary, but instilling the right culture

to support corporate governance is more essential. Culture-based governance, which

comprises (1) governance culture and (2) corporate integrity, sets the moral tone for

governance and accountability.

Governance culture refers to the statements, visions, slogans, values, role models and social

rituals that are unique, to, and used by board members and key executives at both the first and

second tiers to engender corporate governance, transparency and accountability.

Corporate Accountability and Transparency

Corporate accountability is the extent to which a company is transparent in its corporate

activities and responsive to those it serves. Broadly, corporate accountability consists of (1)

financial reporting accountability and (2) strategic decision transparency (“strategic” from the

point of view of decisions that have significant effects or implications on the interests of

shareholders and other major stakeholders). Accountability is essentially a matter of

Page 7 of 20

177

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

disclosure, transparency, and of explaining corporate policies and actions to those to whom the

company is beholden (Wild, 1994; Shearer, 2002).

A firm should be accountable not only to shareholders, but also to all major stakeholders such

as regulators, customers, employees, creditors, suppliers and the local community (Shearer,

2002). A central requirement for corporate accountability is the firm’s ability to signal or

provide relevant information quickly, accurately and effectively to its shareholders,

stakeholders or other principal parties, such as regulators, who motivate and constrain the firm

to behave in both the principals’ and society’s best interests (Awodun, 2018).

Transparency about a company’s governance policies is a critical aspect of corporate

accountability. As long as investors, shareholders and other stakeholders have clear and

accessible information about these policies, the organization is considered transparent.

INNOVATION AND TECHNOLOGICAL DISRUPTIONS

What is seen as technological disruption today is considered as technological advancement at

the beginning and the turn of the 20th century. As technological improvements begin to take

place with efficiency introduced, as a result of those technological advancement, the obvious

potential loss of jobs to machines started to take place, and the perception of man about it all

began to change.

Advances in technology due to innovation has significantly cause changes in the ways that

production and service provisions and processes are carried out, to the extent that it disrupts

the already accepted standards. New ways of doing things, emerging rapidly, has therefore

become a race that enterprises have had to embark upon through research and development

to be the first, rather than the follower.

Several production processes have witnessed some significant disruptions, that even the firms

that are competing in the same sector cannot afford to ignore developments in their industries,

if they must remain relevant in their industry. It is with this background that the issue of

corporate governance and agency theory is being considered within the reality of the disruptive

nature of technological advancement globally.

Changes are taking place now at the speed of light. While a model of a product is being

introduced into the market, a new version is already undergoing development to replace the

newly introduce model. It is thus, a race that the management and the shareholders cannot but

take into consideration in their affairs, as responsibilities are contracted through the reality of

the agency theory.

THE AGENCY-GOVERNANCE-DISRUPTIONS MODEL

Following the review of the various concepts that are embedded in the model presented as

agency-governance-disruptions, it is essential to integrate these concepts and relate them to

operational efficiency, revenue generation/profitability and value delivery. Every organization,

be it private or public, desire to operate at some level of efficiency and add value to the society.

However, these mechanisms of governance, based on the agency theory, and the disruptive

Page 8 of 20

178

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

innovations that technology imposes, are not issues that could be taken for granted by any

organization, be it private or public.

The agency theory and the agency problems crave for solutions in corporate governance, hence

the view that agency theory promotes corporate governance, which is seen as a product of

agency theory. However, the disruptive role of technological innovations has come to have

some significant effects on the ability of corporate governance to deliver on the expectations of

the principal in relation to efficiency, revenue generation/profitability and value delivery.

We examine the effects of this tripod on the anticipated outcomes of firms, as we relate them to

different types of enterprises, private and public alike, in Nigeria, by narrowing our gage to the

universities as our representation of private and public enterprises.

In model 1 below, the relation and relevance of agency theory and corporate governance are

shown in the value delivery capacities of the enterprises, while the impact of the combination

of corporate governance and disruptions through technological innovations is shown through

operational efficiencies indices of the enterprises. On a final analysis, the effect of both agency

theory and technological disruptions is measured by our model on the revenue

generation/profitability index of the enterprises.

Model 1: Agency-governance-disruptions model for operational efficiency, profitability and

value delivery

Put succinctly, agency theory and corporate governance, as put forward by this model, are the

basis of value delivery by any enterprise. Also, corporate governance and technological

disruptions, in line with the model’s proposition, will determine the level of operational

efficiency of the enterprise. Finally, agency theory and technological disruptions, according to

our model, determines the ability of the enterprise to generate revenue that will lead to the

firm’s profitability. The agency-governance-disruptions model, as put forward in this paper, is

therefore an interlocking of the triangular components described above.

Page 10 of 20

180

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

The basis of our investigations in this study are; an examination of (1) the laws establishing the

universities, (2) the ownership and funding sources, (3) the governance structure as

entrenched in the laws, (4) the university’s compliance with the governance structure, (5) the

management operational capacities, (6) the stakeholders’ interests, (7) the revenue

generation/profitability, (8) operational efficiencies, and (9) value delivery.

Our findings are presented and analyzed in the section that follow.

PRESENTATION AND ANALYSIS OF FINDINGS

Out of a total of 120 copies of the questionnaire distributed equally and administered among

the six selected universities, only 112 copies (93%) were returned completed. 58 of the

completed questionnaire (52%) were from the private universities while the remaining 54

(48%) were completed and returned by the public universities. This questionnaire was

administered on members of the universities governing councils and management. The

responses were appropriately analyzed and presented in the tables (5.1 – 5.4) presented in this

paper.

As presented in table 5.1, the six universities (enterprises) have diverse ownership that

necessitated their classification into our private and public enterprises categories. While three

of these six universities are owned by private individuals/organizations, the other three are

owned by government, but at different tiers. What this means is that 50% of the enterprises

sampled are privately owned while the other 50% are publicly owned.

Table 5.1: Analysis of the Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model on Selected Private

and Public Universities in Nigeria

Type of

Enterprise

Ownership Governance

Structure

Agency

Problems

Technology

Disruptions

Operational

Efficiency

Profitability Value

Delivery

IFBU Private BoT/Council AS C. Friendly Efficient Profitable Good

CFBU Private BoT/Council AS C. Friendly Efficient Profitable Good

NFBU Private BoT/Council AS C. Friendly Efficient Profitable Good

FSOU Public MoE/Council MH C. Averse Inefficient Not for Profit Fair

SLOU Public MoE/Council MH C. Averse Inefficient Not for Profit Fair

FDOU Public MoE/Council MH C. Averse Inefficient Not for Profit Fair

Beyond the issue of ownership, which is a bit straight forward because it is easily determined.

Even at the point of approval by the licensing authority, there is the issue of corporate

governance, which is expected to be guided by the law establishing each of the institutions.

Without properly instituted governance structure, the permanent license of the any university

will not be issued.

However, for the corporate governance issues to be properly understood, the agency theory

aspect must be sorted. At the private universities level, their ownership representation is

through the institution of a Board of Trustees (BoT), in line with the law. This ownership

structure is empowered to approve and appoint a Governing Council to direct the affairs of the

university through policy formulation and enforcement of policy implementation by the

management.

Page 11 of 20

181

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

For the publicly owned institutions, however, the situation is a bit different, with the Ministry

of Education (MoE) holding forth on behalf of the government as owner of the universities. The

government, through the ministries (whether at the state or federal levels), therefore, appoints

the Governing Councils for the public universities, also in line with the laws establishing these

universities. The governance structure of both private and public universities thus appears to

reflect the representation of the interests of both the principals and agents appropriately as

expected.

The predominant agency problems in the private and public universities tend to be different.

While at the privately-owned universities, the dominant agency problem is that of averse

selection (AS), at the publicly-owned universities, on the other hand, the agency problem is that

of moral hazard (MH). In the former, the private ownership breathes down the throat of the

management and council, as they want to know all that happens, almost on a day to day basis,

even when they may not understand it, in some or most instances. The case of the latter is

however, different because the ownership and its representation tends not to know what is

happening at the various institutions because of poor reporting mechanisms, some claims of

autonomy and largely due to conflicting interests of representatives attributable to corruption.

When it comes to embracing technological changes/disruptions, particularly as it relates to

bringing about operational efficiency and revenue generation/profitability, the private

universities are easily adaptable and susceptible to change than the public universities. This,

however, cannot be generalized because of the simplicity and complexity of decision making in

private and public universities respectively. While it is very simple and easy to adopt changes

generally at the private universities, the situation is not the same for public universities because

of the complexities of interests.

This is why the mechanism of corporate governance should be appropriated in such a way that

it can help align the interests of the management and the shareholders, and thus alleviate the

negative impact of agency frictions. Recent empirical studies confirm the significance of

corporate governance in the growth process (see Nicolo et al. (2006), Bloom and Van Reenen

(2007), and Claessens and Yurtoglu (2012), among others. According to a report by OECD

(2012), it summarizes this body of evidence by arguing that “corporate governance exerts a

strong influence upon innovative activity and entrepreneurship. Better corporate governance,

therefore, should manifest itself in enhanced corporate performance, and can lead to higher

economic growth.”

Table 5.2: Analysis of the Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model and Agency Theory

Type of

Enterprise

Ownership

Interests

Management

Interests

Stakeholders

Interests

Employees

Interests

Moral

Hazard

Averse

Selection

Agency

Theory

IFBU High Low Low Low Negative Positive Significant

CFBU High Low Low Low Negative Positive Significant

NFBU High Low Low Low Negative Positive Significant

FSOU Low High High High Positive Negative Insignificant

SLOU Low High High High Positive Negative Insignificant

FDOU Low High High High Positive Negative Insignificant

Our findings as presented in table 5.2 show that there is high interest of ownership in the

private universities than what exist in the public universities. While the owners of these private

Page 14 of 20

184

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

day running of the enterprise. The adage that you cannot give what you do not have comes

clearly to bear here.

CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS

In conclusion, the agency-governance-disruptions model reveals that when agency theory

properly aligns with corporate governance, it can reduce agency costs, improves strategic

decision making and implementation such that can lead to improved firm performance and

value delivery. The inherent agency problem, which is traditionally known as the principal- agent problem, is not only restricted to the principal and the agent but also extends to affecting

the value delivery capacity of the enterprise.

The separation of control and ownership in organizations causes different agency problems,

and a series of corporate governance mechanisms can be implemented to mitigate them. The

primary objective of institutionalizing corporate governance is to minimize the agency

problems and ensure that management problems are aligned with those of ownership (Saeid,

& Sakine 2015). This study affirms this position as all the respondents to our questionnaire in

the universities studied agrees with the significance of the alignment of agency theory and

corporate governance for organizational efficiency and effectiveness.

In the course of establishing that corporate governance provides the structure through which

the enterprise sets objectives, the strategy for attaining those objectives and the guidelines for

implementing and monitoring performance, this paper establishes that the agent’s utility

function (management) includes power, security, status, and wealth, while the principal’s

utility function (ownership) are principally to maximize value delivery, market value of their

shares, an ultimately, their wealth.

This study also establishes that agency costs rise not only because of opportunistic behavior of

management, but also from the monitoring and control mechanisms (governance structure)

put in place by stock-holders (ownership). Where there are proper monitoring and control

mechanism through the governance structure, the agency costs are lower, as was found in the

case of private universities.

We also discover that the higher the degree of ownership concentration and presence, the more

likely management’s ability to implement strategic decisions in line with shareholder value

maximization. This position is in line with earlier submissions of (Mizruchi, 1983; Baysinger

and Butler, 1985; Borokhovich et. al., 1996) who believe that effective boards should be

composed of greater proportions of outside directors on the premise that outside directors can

make more exhaustive and profound evaluations of strategic decisions and management

behavior than inside directors.

There are however, exceptions to this position as we uncovered in the cases of some of the

public enterprises. The reasons for these exceptions are tied to other interests, not in alignment

with owner’s interest but personal to the choices of representation that the ownership has put

on the board. Their ability to collude with management and put their unprofessional personal

interests first before that of the enterprise and its owners permits this kind of contradictory

exceptions to the norm.

Page 16 of 20

186

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Awodun, M. O. (2007) “A Comparative Analysis of the Strategies for Managing Multinational and Domestic

Enterprises in Emerging Economies” Doctoral Thesis presented to The Post-Graduate School, Lagos State

University, Ojo, Lagos, July.

Awodun, M. O. (2018) Managing Domestic and Multinational Enterprises in Emerging Markets, Dubai Printing

Press, UAE

Baliga, B. R., Moyer, R. C. & Rao, R. S., (1996) “CEO Duality and Firm Performance: What’s the Fuss?” Strategic

Management Journal 17, pp.41-53.

Barlett, C. A. and Ghoshal S. (1993) “Beyond the M-Form: Toward a Managerial Theory of the Firm” Strategic

Management Journal 14, pp. 23-46.

Barney, J.B. & Hansen, M. H., (1994) “Trustworthiness as a Source of Competitive Advantage” Strategic

Management Journal 15, pp. 175 – 190.

Bartlett, C. A & Ghoshal, S. (2002); Managing Across Borders: The Transnational Solution, Harvard Business

School Press, Boston.

Baysinger, B. D., Butler, H., (1985) “Corporate Governance and the Board of Directors: Performance Effects of

Changes in Board Composition” Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 1, pp. 101-124.

Berle, A. A., & Means Jr., G. C., (1932) The Modern Corporation and Private Property. Macmillan, New York.

Birkinshaw, J. M. & Morrison, A. J., (1995) “Configurations of Strategy and Structure in Subsidiaries of

Multinational Corporations,” Journal of International Business Studies 26, pp. 729-753.

Black, J.S., & Mendenhall, M. (1991) “The U-Curve Adjustment Hypothesis Revisited: A Review and Theoretical

Framework” Journal of International Business Studies. 22 (2), pp. 225-247.

Bonazzi, L. and Islam, S.M.N. (2007), "Agency theory and corporate governance: A study of the effectiveness of

board in their monitoring of the CEO", Journal of Modelling in Management, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 7-23.

Borokhovich, K., Parrino, R. & Trapani, T., (1996) “Outside Directors and CEO Selection” Journal of Financial

Quantitative Analysis, 31, pp. 337-355.

Buckley, P. J. (1990) “Problems and Developments in the Core Theory of International Business”, Journal of

International Business Studies 21, pp, 657-665.

Cannon, T. (1994) Corporate Responsibility. A Textbook on Business Ethics, Governance, Environment: Roles and

Responsibilities. Pitman, London.

Carlson, S. (1975) How Foreign is Foreign Trade? - A Problem in International Business Research. Motala:

Borgströms Tryckeri.

Carlsson, J; Nordegren, A. & Sjoholm F (2005) “International Experience and the Performance of Scandinavian

Firms in China”. International Business Review, (14) pp. 21-40

Chaganti, R. S., Mahajan, V. Sharma S., (1985) “Corporate Board Size, Composition and Corporate Failures in

Retailing Industry’, Journal of Management Studies 22, pp. 401-417.

Chandler, A. D. (1962) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American Industry Enterprises, MIT

Press, Cambridge MA

Page 17 of 20

187

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

Chari, M. D. R, Devaraj, S. and David, P. (2007); “International Diversification and Firm Performance: Role of

Information Technology Investments “Journal of World Business, Vol. 42, Issue 2, June, pp. 184-197.

Cheung, F. S. L and Leung, W. (2007); International Expansion of Transnational Advertising Agencies in China; An

Assessment of the Stages Theory Approach,” International Business Review, Vol. 16 Issue 2, April, pp. 251-268

Davis, J. H. Schoorman, F. D., Donaldson, L., (1997) “Toward a Stewardship Theory of Management,” Academy of

Management Review, pp. 22, 20-47.

Driffield, N., Taylor, K., (2002) “Spillovers from FDI and skill Structures of Host-country Firms”. Discussion Papers

in Economics 02/4. Department of Economics, University of Leicester.

Egelhoff, W. G. (1984) “Patterns of Control in U.S., UK, and European Multinational Corporations” Journal of

International Business Studies 15 (2), pp. 73-83.

Eisenhardt, K. M., (1985). “Control: Organizational and Economic Approaches” Management Science 31, pp. 134-

149.

Eisenhardt, K., & Bourgeois, L. J., (1998). “Politics of Strategic Decision Making in High-velocity Environments:

Toward a Midrange Theory” Academy of Management Journal. 31, pp. 737-770.

Fama, E. F. Jensen, M. C. (1983) “Separation of Ownership and Control” Journal of Law & Economics 26, pp. 301-

325.

Freeman, R., & Reed, D., (1983) “Stockholders and Stakeholders: A New Perspective on Corporate Governance”,

California Management Review 25 (3), pp. 88-106.

Frost, T. S., (2001) “The Geographic Sources of Foreign Subsidiaries’ Innovations” Strategic Management Journal

22, pp. 101-123.

Geringer, J. M., Beamish, P. W. and DaCosta, R. C. (1989) “Diversification Strategy and Internationalization:

Implications for MNE Performance” Strategic Management Journal 10, pp. 109-119.

Gibson, R (1998) “Rethinking Business” in Gibson, R (ed) Rethinking the Future, Nicholas Brealey, London pp. 1-

14

Ginsberg A. and Grant, J. H (1985) “Research on Strategic Change: Theoretical and Methodology Issues” Academy

of Management Proceedings 11-15, Sam Diego, CA

Goshal, S. and Nohria, N., (1989) “International Differentiation Within Multinational Corporations” Strategic

Management Journal 10. pp. 323-337.

Goyal, A. (2007); “Distant Labour Supply, Skill and Induced Technical Change,” Information Economics and Policy,

Vol. 19, Issue 2, June, pp. 133-150

Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V., (1991) “Knowledge Flows and the Structure of Control within Multinational

Corporations,” Academy of Management Review 16, pp. 768-792.

Harzing, A. W. K. (1999) Managing the Multinationals: An International Study of Control Mechanisms, Edward

Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.

Hill, C., and Jones, T., (1992). “Stakeholder-Agency Theory,” Journal of Management Studies, 29, pp. 134-154.

Page 18 of 20

188

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Iqbal, Z. and French, D.W (2007) “Executive Share Ownership, Trading Behaviour, and Corporate Control:

Evidence form Top Management Turnover during Financial Distress,” Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 59,

Issue 4, July-Aug., pp. 298-312

Janeba, E. (2007); “International Trade and Consumption Network Externalities,” European Economic Review,

Vol. 51, Issue 4, May. pp 781-803

Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H., (1976) “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership

Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics (3), pp. 305-360.

Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. E. (1977) “The Internationalization Process of the Firm: A Model of Knowledge

Development and Increasing Foreign Market Commitments,” Journal of International Business Studies, 8, pp. 23-

32.

Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. E. (1990) “The Mechanism of Internationalization”, International Marketing Review, 4,

pp. 11-24.

Kim, B., Prescott, J. E. & Kim, S. M. (2005) “Differentiated Governance of Foreign Subsidiaries in Transnational

Corporations: An Agency Theory Perspective,” Journal of International Management, (11) pp. 43-66.

Kim, K. & Limpaphayom, P., (1998) “A Test of the Two-tier Corporate Governance Structure: The Case of

Japanese Keiretsu” Journal of Financial Resources 21 (1), pp. 37-52.

Kimberly, J. R., & Rottman, D. B. (1987) “Environment, Organization and Effectiveness: A Biographical Approach,”

Journal of Management Studies, 24 (6), pp. 595-622.

Kobrin, S. J. (1994) “Is there a relationship between a Geocentric Mind-set and Multinational Strategy?” Journal

International Business Studies 25, pp. 493-511.

LaPorta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1998) “Law and Finance” Journal of Political

Economy 106, pp. 1113-1155.

Lipsey, R., (2002) “Home and Host Country Effects of FDI”. NBER Working Paper No. w9293 (Online.

http://papers.nber.org/papers/w9293).

Lorsh, J., (1989) Pawns and Potentates: The Reality of America’s Corporate Boards, Harvard Business School

Press, Boston, M.A.

Luo, Y., (1999) “International Strategy and Subsidiary Performance in China, Thunderbird” International Business

Review 41 (2), pp. 153-178.

Luo, Y. (2005a) “Corporate Governance and Accountability in Multinational Enterprises: Concepts and Agenda,”

Journal of International Management, (11) pp. 1-18.

Luo, Y. (2005b) “How does Globalization affect Corporate Governance and Accountability?” A Perspective from

MNEs”, Journal of International Management, (11) pp. 19-41.

Luo, Y., & Zhao H., (2004). “Corporate Link and Competitive Strategy in Multinational Enterprises: A Perspective

from Subsidiaries Seeking Host Market Penetration” Journal of International Management 10, pp. 77-105.

Malnight, T. W. (1996) “The Transition from Decentralized to Network-Based MNC Structures: An Evolutionary

Perspective” Journal International Business Studies 26, pp. 43-65.

Mitnick, B., (1994) “The Hazards of Agency”. Paper presented in the 1994 Annual Meetings of the American

Political Science Association, New York Hilton.

Page 19 of 20

189

Awodun, M., & Adam, L. (2025). The Agency-Governance-Disruptions Model for Operational Efficiency, Profitability and Value Delivery: An Application

to Private and Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Archives of Business Research, 13(03). 171-190.

URL: http://doi.org/10.14738/abr.1303.18487

Mizruchi, M. S., (1983) “Who Controls Whom? An Experimentation of the Relation between Management and

Boards of Directors in Large American Corporations” Academy of Management Review 8, pp. 426-435.

Myers, M. B, Droge, C and Cheung, M. S. (2007); “The Fit of Home to Foreign Market Environment: An Exploratory

Study of the Relationship of Congruence of Performance” Journal of World Business, Vol. 42, Issue 2, June, pp 170-

183.

Nohria, N., Ghoshal, S., (1994) “Differentiated Fit and Shared Values: Alternatives for Managing Headquarters

Subsidiary Relations” Strategic Management Journal 15, pp. 491-502.

O’Donnell, S. W. (2000) “Managing Foreign Subsidiaries: Agents of Headquarters, or An Interdependent

Network?” Strategic Management Journal 21, pp. 525-548.

Osuagwu, L. (2002) “TQM Strategies in a Developing Economy: Empirical Evidence from Nigerian Companies”,

Business Process Management Journal, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 140-160

Otokiti, S. O. (2007) International Business; How to Get Started in the International Business Environment, Dubai

Printing Press, Dubai, United Arab Emirates.

Parkinson, J., (1994) Corporate Power and Responsibility, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Perlmutter, H. (1969) “The Tortuous Evolution of the Multinational Corporation” Columbia Journal World

Business 4, pp, 9-18.

Pfeffer, J & Salancik, G. R (1978): The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Perspective,

Harper & Row, New York.

Roberts, J. (2004) The Modern Firm: Organizational Design for Performance and Growth, Oxford University Press,

Oxford

Rosenzweig, P. M. Singh, J. V., (1991). “Organizational Environments and the Multinational Enterprise” Academy

of Management Review 16 (2), pp. 340-361.

Roth, K., & O’Donnell, S., (1996) “Foreign Subsidiary Compensation Strategy: An Agency Theory Perspective”

Academy of Management Journal 39, pp. 678-703.

Saeid, Homayoun & Sakine Homayoun (2015) “Agency theory and corporate governance,” International Business

Management, 9 (5), pp. 805-815.

Shearer, T., (2002). “Ethics and Accountability: From the For itself to the For-the-other” Accounting, Organization

Society. 27 (6), pp. 541 559.

Singh, J., & Harianto, F. (1989). “Management-Board Relationships, Takeover Risk, and the Adoption of Golden

Parachutes,” Academy of Management Journal, pp. 32, 7-24.

Solomon, J. & Solomon, A. (2004) Corporate Governance and Accountability, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester.

Tihanyi L., Johnson R. A, Hoskisson, R.E., & Hitt, M. A. (2003) “Institutional Ownership Differences and

International Diversification: The Effect of Boards of Technological Opportunity” Academy of Management

Journal 46, pp. 195-211.

Todeva, E. (2005) “Governance, Control and Coordination in Network Context: The Cases of Japanese Keiretsu

and Sogo Shosha,” Journal of International Management (11) pp. 87-109.

Page 20 of 20

190

Archives of Business Research (ABR) Vol. 13, Issue 03, March-2025

Services for Science and Education – United Kingdom

Tosi, H. L. & Gomez-Mejia, L. R., (1989). “The Decoupling of CEO and Performance: An Agency Theory

Perspective” Administrative Science Quarterly, pp. 34, 169-189.

Tricker, R., (1994) Corporate Governance: Practices, Procedures and Powers in British Companies and their Boards

of Directors, Gower Press, Aldershot, UK.

Vargas-Hernández, J. G., & Teodoro Cruz, M. E. (2018). “Corporate governance and agency theory: Megacable

case,” Corporate Governance and Sustainability Review, 1(2), 59-69.

Watson, S & Weaver, G. R (2004) “How Internationalization Affects Corporate Ethics: Formal Structure and

Information Management Behaviour” Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 56, Issue 1, Jan-Feb. pp. 63-70

Wild, J. J. (1994). “Managerial Accountability to Shareholders: Audit Committees and the Explanatory Power of

Earnings for Returns,” Brookling Accounting Review 26 (4), pp. 353-370.

Zajac, E. J., Westphal, J. W., (1994) “The Cost and Benefits of Managerial Incentives and Monitoring in Large U.S.

Corporations: When is More not Better?” Strategic Management Journal 15, pp. 112-121.